Unobservable shocks as carriers of contagion · 2019. 11. 29. · the seminal contribution but also...

42
1 Unobservable shocks as carriers of contagion Mardi Dungey a , George Milunovich b , Susan Thorp c; a School of Economics and Finance, University of Tasmania; CFAP, University of Cambridge b Department of Economics, Macquarie University c School of Finance and Economics, University of Technology, Sydney This version: 2 November 2009 Abstract We propose an identied structural GARCH model to disentangle the dynamics of nancial market crises. We distinguish between the hypersensitivity of a domestic market in crisis to news from foreign non-crisis markets, and the contagion imported to a tranquil domestic market from foreign crises. The model also enables us to connect unobserved structural shocks with their source markets using variance decompositions and to compare the size and dynamics of impulses during crises periods with tranquil period impulses. To illustrate, we apply the method to data from the 1997-1998 Asian nancial crisis which consists of a complicated set of interacting crises. We nd signicant hypersensitivity and contagion between these markets but also show that links may strengthen or weaken. Impulse response functions for an equally weighted equity portfolio show the increasing dominance of Korean and Hong Kong shocks during the crises and covariance responses demonstrate multiple layers of contagion e/ects. JEL classication: G01; C51 Keywords: Contagion; Structural GARCH Corresponding author. Tel.:+61 2 9514 7784; fax: +61 2 9415 7711. Email addresses: [email protected] (M.Dungey), [email protected] (G. Milunovich), [email protected] (S. Thorp).

Transcript of Unobservable shocks as carriers of contagion · 2019. 11. 29. · the seminal contribution but also...

  • 1

    Unobservable shocks as carriers of contagion

    Mardi Dungeya, George Milunovichb, Susan Thorpc;�

    aSchool of Economics and Finance, University of Tasmania; CFAP, University of

    Cambridge

    bDepartment of Economics, Macquarie University

    cSchool of Finance and Economics, University of Technology, Sydney

    This version: 2 November 2009

    Abstract

    We propose an identied structural GARCH model to disentangle the dynamics of

    nancial market crises. We distinguish between the hypersensitivity of a domestic market

    in crisis to news from foreign non-crisis markets, and the contagion imported to a tranquil

    domestic market from foreign crises. The model also enables us to connect unobserved

    structural shocks with their source markets using variance decompositions and to compare

    the size and dynamics of impulses during crises periods with tranquil period impulses. To

    illustrate, we apply the method to data from the 1997-1998 Asian nancial crisis which

    consists of a complicated set of interacting crises. We nd signicant hypersensitivity

    and contagion between these markets but also show that links may strengthen or weaken.

    Impulse response functions for an equally weighted equity portfolio show the increasing

    dominance of Korean and Hong Kong shocks during the crises and covariance responses

    demonstrate multiple layers of contagion e¤ects.

    JEL classication: G01; C51

    Keywords: Contagion; Structural GARCH

    �Corresponding author. Tel.:+61 2 9514 7784; fax: +61 2 9415 7711.Email addresses: [email protected] (M.Dungey), [email protected] (G. Milunovich),

    [email protected] (S. Thorp).

  • 2

    1. Introduction

    An important unanswered question concerning nancial crises is whether it is possible

    to separately identify and measure shocks emerging from a particular source market.

    As well as disrupting markets in the country where trouble begins, nancial crises may

    spread turmoil into foreign markets in a phenomenon often labelled contagion.1 Here we

    develop a method for separating these increased crisis-period linkages into two categories.

    The rst category is hypersensitivity to information from elsewhere during a local crisis,

    in other words, where turmoil at home changes the way a domestic market reacts to

    news from foreign markets. The second category is changes to the impact of news from a

    troubled foreign market on (potentially non-crisis) domestic markets - we restrict the label

    contagionto this second e¤ect. These categories can be separately measured whenever

    domestic and foreign crises are not totally coincident.2

    This distinction is not an unnecessary abstraction since each category supports dif-

    ferent crisis management and prevention policies. While the domestic policy makers of

    a country in crisis are likely to be interested in preventing increasing hypersensitivity,

    that is, preventing their own troubled market from over-reacting to external news, they

    have little incentive to prevent their crisis spreading to foreign markets. On the other

    hand, such a crisis may generate externalities to other countries in the form of contagion

    so that governments and market participants in non-crisis countries may want to protect

    their markets from foreign-sourced trouble, if possible. The existence of these externali-

    ties is consistent with the agenda for coordinated global reforms in regulation, nancial

    infrastructure and instrument design following major incidents.

    Here we model contemporaneous linkages between nancial markets during normal

    times, as well as changes during crisis periods. In order to capture the well-known clus-

    tering of nancial returns, we base our analysis in a multivariate GARCH model of asset1Consistent with recent literature, we here refer to purecontagion in the terminology of Dornbusch

    et al. (2000) and Kaminsky and Reinhart (2002), as distinct from crisis-driven changes in fundamentallinkages.

    2Theoretical models of contagion propose mechanisms such as information asymmetry and portfoliorebalancing (Kodres and Pritsker, 2002; Yuan, 2005), institutional and regulatory linkages, and rela-tionship complexity (Allen and Gale, 2000; Brusco and Catiglionesi, 2007; Pavlova and Rigobon, 2007).Recent network theory tallies particularly well with the empirical framework developed here, see Allenand Babus, (2008).

  • 3

    market interaction. However we do not simply work with the standard spillovers from

    a reduced form MGARCH, instead, we model contemporaneous structural interactions

    between concurrently trading markets using an extension to the work of Caporale et al.

    (2005) and Rigobon and Sack (2004) on identication via heteroskedasticity. Within the

    framework we allow di¤erent regimes, corresponding to periods of tranquility and to a

    series of crises experienced during the sample period. One advantage of our structural

    GARCH approach is that the model identies the underlying independent shocks which

    are key to sourcing transmissions between asset markets.

    We also implement an innovative approach to classifying and interpreting structural

    shocks by attributing them to a specic source market using variance decompositions.

    Unlike previous approaches, this method is data-driven and does not rely on arbitrary

    restrictions such as market hierarchies, orthogonalizations or chronology. Once we have

    matched structural shocks to their market of origin, it becomes possible to track the

    size and duration of innovations from any particular source and compare their relative

    importance under di¤erent regimes (that is in the di¤erent crises or tranquil periods). The

    rich interactions captured in our model contribute to the developing empirical literature

    on cross-country and cross-asset-market crisis models. In addition, our technique can

    be applied to other crises where the source of trouble is unclear, enabling observers to

    distinguish the real underlying drivers of contagion from simple crisis chronology.

    Data from the Asian crisis of 1997-1998 o¤ers a tangle of interrelated information

    ows between regional markets; we can untangle key elements of crisis transmission using

    our structural model. Taking the perspective of an international investor, we model daily

    U.S. dollar returns to major equity market indices during the crises in Asia over the

    period 1997-1998. The sample consists of Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea and Thailand,

    each of which had their own crises and potentially also received transmissions from other

    crisis countries. The results show statistically signicant contagion between a number

    of countries and some evidence for hypersensitivity. Not all signicant crisis changes

    were associated with increases in market integration; several linkages weakened. Our

    ndings are consistent with the hypothesis that in many cases the crisis country had

  • 4

    weak incentives to slow down the spread of turbulence to neighbors, while nearby markets

    under the threat of contagion had more cause to take a proactive role in curbing the crisis

    of an a¤ected neighbor, or once a crisis has developed, to look for protection either via

    domestic regulation or international policy coordination.

    Further analysis using innovation accounting for an equally-weighted portfolio of eq-

    uity indices shows the rise in importance of Korean and Hong Kong-sourced shocks as

    transmitters of contagion in the region, a reaction made more marked by the Hong Kong

    markets hypersensitivity to news from Indonesia during October 1997. The cross market

    e¤ects revealed by impulse responses on covariances between assets show how the covari-

    ances between non crisis countries can be a¤ected by the events unfolding elsewhere.

    The paper begins with a brief review of the modelling of contagion, the di¢ culties

    this presents for policy makers in using the results, and how this motivates the current

    paper. In Section 3 we set out the modelling strategy and Section 4 explains the dynamic

    analysis. The Asian data and estimation results are reported in Sections 5 and 6. Section

    7 concludes.

    2. Motivation

    Crisis-driven changes in the transmission of asset market shocks are often labelled

    contagion. Theoretical models of contagion have emphasized the role of information ow,

    (Akhigbe and Madura, 2001), portfolio rebalancing (Kodres and Pritzker, 2002) and

    institutional linkages (Allen and Gale, 2000). Most recently, the linkages created through

    networks in international banking have come to attention as a means of transmitting

    crises through nancial institutions; for an overview see Allen and Babus (2008).

    Empirical contagion models aim to measure these changes in the relationships between

    asset markets. For example Rigobon (2001) emphasizes increased correlations. This may

    come through increased strength of existing linkages, as in Eglo¤ et al. (2007) who inves-

    tigate microstructural channels when looking at credit risk transmission, or via changes

    in the parameters connecting assets, such as Yang et al. (2009). Alternatively, contagion

    may be viewed as the opening of new channels of transmission during crisis, see Dungey

    and Martin (2007). Other authors emphasize nonlinearities and use threshold models

  • 5

    to separate tranquil and crisis periods; such as Bae et al. (2003) and Billio and Peliz-

    zon (2005) or more recently the potential for a domino e¤ect of crises in Markwat et al.

    (2009). An acknowledged aspect of each of these approaches is the need to rst control

    for general conditions, such as in Giesecke and Weber (2004) who control for common

    e¤ects in credit default contagion, Dungey and Martin (2007) who use a common factor

    approach and Eglo¤ et al. (2007) who di¤erentiate macrostructural channels.

    Crisis prevention and mitigation is a key goal of nancial regulators. Suggestions for

    mitigating or preventing crises include Diamond and Dybvig (1983), who argue for deposit

    insurance to stop runs, and Castiglionesi (2007), who argues that central banks can use

    reserve requirements to compensate for the incomplete contracts which allow contagion

    to exist.3 Network theory proposes optimal degrees of connectedness between nancial

    institutions, where both the number of connections and the form of those connections -

    whether to the centre or periphery institutions - matters. (See Allen and Gale (2000) for

    the seminal contribution but also Frexias et al. (2000), Hasman and Samartin (2008),

    and for empirical evidence, Furne (2003).)

    Knowing how to respond to a crisis depends on more than simply knowing that

    contagion exists, or measuring the size of these e¤ects, although these are undoubtedly

    important aspects. To formulate an appropriate crisis response it is also critical to be able

    to trace the source of the crisis. For example, the Bank of England, viewing constraints on

    the economy as emerging from the banking sector, provided nancial support to improve

    banks balance sheets in order to tackle reduced credit to businesses and households.

    Thus far, the empirical literature on nancial contagion has not addressed this issue, but

    simply identies changes in the relationship between markets.

    Here we provide a method for identifying both the existence of contagion between mar-

    kets, and to identify the direction of transmission. We distinguish between contagion,

    which is the impact of a crisis in one market on another non-crisis market, and hyper-

    sensitivity, which is the increased sensitivity a market in crisis experiences to externally

    generated shocks. The distinction between contagion and hypersensitivity is important

    3Note that the Castiglionesi (2007) model has an acknowledged moral hazard problem.

  • 6

    for policy making. If a market is in crisis, it is most likely that domestic policy makers

    are more concerned about hypersensitivity than contagion - that is they are concerned

    about the increased reaction of the domestic economy to foreign shocks during this time,

    and less concerned about the e¤ects of their own crisis on others. On the other hand,

    foreign countries who are not experiencing a crisis are concerned mainly about limiting

    the spread of the crisis and hence about the e¤ects of contagion. This highlights an

    important tension in forming international agreements on crisis management - the incen-

    tives of the crisis and non-crisis countries are quite di¤erent. In the Asian nancial crisis

    of 1997-1998, for example, the actions of Malaysia in limiting capital ows from the end

    of August 1998 is a good example of a country concerned with limiting hypersensitivity,

    while the IMF programs of the time can be portrayed as attempts to limit contagion to

    developed markets. In this paper we look to the empirical separation of these e¤ects.

    3. Modelling strategy

    Consider a vector of k ltered asset returns Yt;which are all potentially contempora-

    neously interlinked in tranquil periods, so that the system can be described as

    BYt = ut (1)

    where B is a k�k matrix of coe¢ cients representing these non-crisis linkages, bij, normal-

    ized on the diagonal elements of B: The lter removes non-zero means, auto-correlation,

    spillovers, and contemporaneous common factors. A typical choice of lter is a VAR(1) in

    returns with the US short term interest rate as an exogenous variable representing global

    nancial conditions; see Forbes and Rigobon (2002). The k � 1 vector ut represents the

    idiosyncratic shocks in the system,

    ut = gt"t (2)

    "it � iidN(0; 1) (3)

    where gt is a k � k diagonal matrix. (Scaled structural innovations ut are uncorrelated.)

    The underlying shocks themselves, given by k�1 vector "t; are distributed i:i:d: standard

  • 7

    normal: Appendix A gives a detailed k = 2 dimensional example of the model and

    dynamics.

    Here, we capture hypersensitivity and contagion as a change in the strength of linkages

    between asset returns during a crisis consistent with the approach of Forbes and Rigobon

    (2002), Favero and Giavazzi (2002), and Pesaran and Pick (2007) amongst others.4 (These

    additional parameters can also detect nonlinearities in the mean equations associated with

    the crises.) We explicitly model both the ability of countries to transmit contagion abroad

    and any super-sensitivity to foreign shocks during periods of domestic crisis. In the past,

    these two e¤ects have not been separately distinguished nor empirically quantied, both

    being captured in a single measure. We model tranquil and crisis periods as follows:

    (B+BcDt +DtBs)Yt = B�Yt = ut; (4)

    with BcDt and DtBs representing the linkages present in crisis periods. Contagion

    (indicated by subscript c) is modelled as the additional impact on the asset market in

    home country i during a crisis in foreign country j, given by the parameters bc;ij (bc;ii = 0)

    in each equation, the elements of the k � k matrix Bc. Hypersensitivity (indicated by

    subscript s), is given by the parameter bs;ij in each equation (elements of the k � k

    matrix Bs) measuring the additional impact of foreign shocks during a domestic crisis.

    Each period of crisis is identied using an indicator variable Di;t which is one during

    the crisis in home country i and zero otherwise, elements of the k � k diagonal matrix

    Dt. The relevance of each instance of contagion and hypersensitivity is tested by the

    signicance of the parameters bc;ij and bs;ij respectively: In the case of no contagion or

    hypersensitivity in the system bc;ij = bs;ij = 0 for all i; j:

    4Choice of crisis periods is described in section 5 below.

  • 8

    The detailed structure of equation (4) is

    0BBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBBB@

    266666664

    1 �b12 � � � �b1k

    �b21 1 � � � �b2k...

    .... . .

    ...

    �bk1 �bk2 � � � 1

    377777775+

    266666664

    0 �bc;12 � � � �bc;1k

    �bc;21 0 � � � �bc;2k...

    .... . .

    ...

    �bc;k1 �bc;k2 � � � 0

    377777775

    266666664

    D1;t 0 � � � 0

    0 D2;t � � � 0...

    .... . .

    ...

    0 0 � � � Dk;t

    377777775+

    266666664

    D1;t 0 � � � 0

    0 D2;t � � � 0...

    .... . .

    ...

    0 0 � � � Dk;t

    377777775

    266666664

    0 �bs;12 � � � �bs;1k

    �bs;21 0 � � � �bs;2k...

    .... . .

    ...

    �bs;k1 �bs;k2 � � � 0

    377777775

    1CCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCCA

    266666664

    y1t

    y2t...

    ykt

    377777775=

    266666664

    u1t

    u2t...

    ukt

    377777775

    (5)

    and for each i

    yit =kX

    j=1;j 6=i

    bijyjt +kX

    j=1;j 6=i

    bc;ijDjtyjt +kX

    j=1;j 6=i

    bs;ijDityjt + uit: (6)

    We also model the known volatility clustering of nancial markets returns inYt: Given

    the structure of (2) to (4) it is straightforward to see that

    B�Yt � (0; E[Gt]); (7)

    where Gt = gt"t"0tg0t is a k � k diagonal matrix of the squares of the elements of the

    matrix gt.

    The conditional covariance matrix of the structural shocks is a GARCH(1,1), specied

    for Gt as

    Gt = diag[ + � (ut�1 � ut�1)] + �Gt�1; (8)

    where is a k�1 vector of constants, i, � is a k�k diagonal matrix of ARCH coe¢ cients

  • 9

    and � is a k � k diagonal matrix of GARCH coe¢ cients. So for each country i

    g2ii;t = i + �iiu2i;t�1 + � iig

    2ii;t�1: (9)

    Since both Gt�1 and ut�1 are unobservable, we specify the system as a reduced form,

    Yt= �t; where �t := (B�)�1ut = Aut: (10)

    The joint conditional distribution of the vector of ltered returns is

    Yt � N(0;Ht); (11)

    and we work with this reduced form covariance matrix, Ht; which can be estimated as a

    multivariate GARCH process in the ltered returns vector Yt, Ht = AGtA0:

    Identication of the structural parameters in B� from the estimated value of Ht de-

    pends on establishing the link between the structural parameters and the reduced form.

    The lower diagonal elements of the reduced form covariance matrix Ht can be expressed

    as 5

    vech (Ht) = C0 +C1 (�t�1 � �t�1) +C2ht�1 (12)

    where C0 is a k(k+1)=2� 1 vector of constant coe¢ cients, C1 is a k(k+1)=2�k matrix

    of ARCH coe¢ cients , C2 is a k(k + 1)=2� k matrix of GARCH coe¢ cients and ht is a

    k � 1 vector of the diagonal elements of Ht.

    To establish the relationship between the coe¢ cients ofHt and the structural parame-

    ters we begin with the vector of ARCH terms. Relying on the independence of structural

    shocks, we set cross products to zero and write

    (A �A)�1 �t�1 � �t�1 = (ut�1 � ut�1) : (13)5In the case of non-zero mean data the following expressions would be complicated by the additional

    interactions of any common factors with the independent factors.

  • 10

    Next we can make a similar transformation of the GARCH terms:

    (A �A)�1 ht�1 = vecd (Gt�1) ; (14)

    where vecd is the vector of the diagonal elements of the matrix.

    If we again rewrite Ht = AGtA0 in vech (�) form and dene the required transforma-

    tion of the A matrix as Av, a k(k + 1)=2 � k matrix of products of the elements of A;

    then the reduced form covariance matrix is comprised of structural shocks and structural

    parameters,

    vech (Ht) = Av +Av� (ut�1 � ut�1) +Av�vecd (Gt�1) : (15)

    Finally by substituting equation (13) and equation (14) we can link the C matrices of

    the reduced-form MGARCH and the structural parameters,

    vech (Ht) = Av +Av� (A �A)�1 (�t�1 � �t�1) +Av� (A �A)�1 ht�1: (16)

    Estimation and identication of structural form parameters therefore depends on the

    estimation of the reduced form covariance matrix expressed in terms of structural pa-

    rameters. The coe¢ cients from the reduced form in equation (12) provide k(k + 1)=2

    parameters in the C0 matrix, k2(k + 1)=2 parameters in each of the C1 and C2 matrices

    for a total of (2k + 1)(k + 1)k=2. The structural model contains 3k(k� 1) parameters in

    the B� matrix and 3k GARCH parameters for a total of 3k2: (In the four-country exam-

    ple estimated below there are 48 structural parameters and 90 reduced form parameters,

    unlike a conventional identication problem where the number of structural parameters

    typically exceeds the number of reduced form moment conditions.)

    The MGARCH structure of the model provides us with additional scores (rst order

    conditions) that overcome problems of identication and endogeneity. Overcoming the

    endogeneity problem of this simultaneous model is possible due to the fact that we do

    not directly estimate the contemporaneous structural model but indirectly estimate struc-

  • 11

    tural parameters as part of the time-varying reduced form covariance matrix. There is no

    endogeneity problem in the estimation of the reduced form covariance matrix. Structural

    parameters are non-linear transformations of the reduced form parameters in this model,

    and although an analytical proof of identication is di¢ cult, we have evidence for local

    numerical identication since we consistently achieve convergence in the maximization

    of the structural likelihood function from a range of starting values.6 Numerical iden-

    tication of the structural parameters is helped by low correlation between the ltered

    returns series. We also conrm the numerical identication and optimization procedure

    by estimating the model from simulated data.

    4. Dynamics

    Innovation accounting within the SGARCH model gives a mapping of the dynamics

    of transmissions between markets. We introduce a new approach to connecting each

    structural shock to a source market without resorting to standard identifying restrictions

    such as Choleski decomposition or long-run variance assumptions. Our method relies on

    an interpretation of variance decomposition: we treat the shocks which contribute the

    largest part of each domestic-market forecast error variance during the tranquil period

    as emanating from that market. This interpretation is possible because we estimate the

    entire (normalized) structural model and can thus work with the structural innovations

    directly, rather than their reduced form counterparts. Consequently we do not need to

    apply arbitrary restrictions to the structural model to trace turbulence during crises back

    to a specic source.

    We make tranquil period dynamics the benchmark then examine the dynamics of both

    contagion and hypersensitivity e¤ects during periods of crisis. We take the position of an

    international investor holding an equally weighted USD portfolio of each of the market

    indices in the model, and track the impact of structural impulses on the volatility of this

    naive portfolio. While this is a convenient application of the processes and e¤ects, the

    6Rothenberg (1971, Theorem 7) shows that for non-linear systems of equations, under weak regularityconditions, an overly strong su¢ ciency condition for global identication of structural parameters ismet when the Jacobian matrix of partial derivatives with respect to the structural parameters has apositive determinant and the sum of the Jacobian and its transpose is positive semidenite.

  • 12

    potential for exploring contagion dynamics in this model are much wider than this simple

    portfolio example. The model can be used to track individual transmission paths for

    shocks from all domestic and foreign sources under each of the four crises in the sample,

    separating hypersensitivity and contagion e¤ects.7

    The 1�step ahead conditional forecast error variance for Yt is the tted value of the

    reduced form conditional covariance matrix:

    vart [Yt+1 � Et (Yt+1)] = vart [Aut+1 � Et (Aut+1)]

    = Ht+1jt; (17)

    treating all estimated parameter values as known with certainty.

    The conditionally heteroskedastic properties of the model mean that forecast errors

    vary with realized volatility at time t, and consequently each forecast error depends on the

    specic history of volatility at time t and more generally on the forecast horizon (Gallant

    et al. 1993 and Engle and Ng 1993). Since this process generates almost as many forecast

    errors at the 1-step horizon as there are observations in the sample, we need a way of

    summarizing the information without losing the value of conditioning. Here we compute

    the forecast errors for both tranquil and crisis periods for each time t, and stack them by

    size, creating an empirical distribution of conditional forecast error variances, e¤ectively

    based on a series of random draws from the structural error distributions. We then select

    empirical quantiles from the tranquil and crisis period distributions and compare the

    forecast error variances and decompositions.

    The forecast error variance is a non-linear function of structural parameters and

    structural shocks, however the identication of structural parameters during estimation

    means that it is possible to numerically identify the structural errors via the relationship

    B�Yt = gt"t so that g�1t B�Yt = "t: The percentage of the forecast error variance at time

    7One could ask, for example, What is the e¤ect on the volatility path of returns to the Thai stockmarket of a shock emerging from Hong Kong, during the Indonesian market crisis?, and derive animpulse response function to estimate the size and duration of this specic e¤ect.

  • 13

    t, V Di;jjt; for market return yi that is due to each structural shock "j is computed as

    V Di;jjt =

    �Agj;t+1jtg

    0j;t+1jtA

    0�ii�

    Agt+1jtg0t+1jtA

    0�ii

    � 100; (18)

    where gj;t+1jt is the jth column of the 1�period ahead forecast standard deviation matrix

    gt+1jt: Each of the structural shocks "j is linked to the ith market if

    V Di;jjt > VDi;mjt for m = 1; :::; k;m 6= i:8 (19)

    Further, in the event that an investor holds an equally-weighted portfolio across the

    k markets, the forecast error variance decomposition for the portfolio indicates the shift

    in portfolio risk associated with exposure to a particular market during a crisis. The

    proportion of portfolio volatility associated with each structural shock component can be

    computed as

    V Dp;jjt =w0Agj;t+1jtg

    0j;t+1jtA

    0w

    w0Agt+1jtg0t+1jtA

    0w� 100 (20)

    where w is a k � 1 vector of portfolio weights, in our example, 1=k. Using (20) we can

    compare the mean contribution of each shock to portfolio variance during the tranquil

    and crisis periods.

    Conditional impulse responses for the variance of the individual returns can be com-

    puted using the approach of Lin (1997). For the equally-weighted portfolio the response

    is the expectation at time t of the partial derivative of w0Ht+nw with respect to "2j;t ,

    given by

    Et

    �@w0Ht+njtw

    @"2j;t

    �= Et

    �w0A

    @Gt+njt@"2j;t

    A0w

    �: (21)

    The conditional impulse response of individual components (ij) of the portfolio co-

    variance matrix is computed as

    8This ordering would not be complete or unique if there were more than one market to which theshock "j contributed the majority of forecast error variance or if any two structural shocks accountedfor the same proportion of variance for one market. Neither of these cases arise in this application.

  • 14

    Et

    �@Ht+njt@"2j;t

    �ij

    = Et

    �A@Gj;t+njt@"2j;t

    A0�ij

    : (22)

    Using the same method as for the variance decompositions, we compute an impulse

    response conditioning on each time t volatility history, stack each time path into an

    empirical distribution and draw out specic quantiles for comparison.

    5. The Asian crisis

    During 1997-1998 there were multiple crises in a number of countries in Asia across

    several di¤erent classes of assets. The debate over the causes of, and links between, these

    crises remains unresolved.

    The discursive literature at the time of the Asian crisis viewed pressure in the Hong

    Kong equity market around October 1997 as leading to pressure on equity markets in

    other countries, and particularly in precipitating crisis in Korean markets. Four of the

    major countries involved in the turmoil during 1997-1998 were Thailand, Indonesia, Korea

    and Hong Kong. However empirical evidence on contagion during this period is mixed.

    On one hand, Forbes and Rigobon (2002) nd little evidence for contagion in these

    equity markets using bivariate correlation tests, and Bekiros and Georgoutsos (2008b)

    reach a similar conclusion using an extreme value approach. On the other hand, each

    of Baig and Goldfajn (1999), Caporale et al. (2003) and Baur and Schulze (2005) nd

    statistically signicant contagion e¤ects. Markwat et al. (2009) use ordered logit models

    to identify a domino e¤ect where local crisis evolve into more widespread and severe

    events and Candelon et al. (2008), using multivariate synchronization indexes, nd a

    sudden increase in bull and bear market synchronization among Asian stock markets in

    1997. However the dynamic properties of the SGARCH model set out above allow us to

    go further than testing for contagion e¤ects. We can also identify the main sources of

    turbulence for each countrys crisis and gauge their relative importance to a diversied

    investor.

    We construct returns as the residuals from a VAR(1) on the log changes in the daily US

    dollar-valued equity market indices for each country, including also the contemporaneous

  • 15

    3-month US Treasury Bill rate as a proxy for an exogenous common shock, following

    Forbes and Rigobon (2002).9 The full sample runs from 2 January 1992 to 9 January

    2007. Figure 1 shows the time series of returns.

    The model proposed in Section 3 requires an exogenous identication of the indicator

    variables, Di for i = 1; :::; k; where k is the total number of equity indices involved so we

    collate crisis dates for each individual country from existing sources. We set the Hong

    Kong crisis period as 27 October 1997 to 17 November 1997 (Billio and Pelizzon, 2003;

    Rigobon, 2003) and the Indonesian crisis period as 1 January 1998 to 27 February 1998

    encompassing the period of high volatility in returns associated with political uncertainty

    and IMF negotiations. The Korean crisis occurs in the lead up to successful renegotiation

    of its debt moratorium with the IMF on 24th December 1997. Clearly (Panel C in Figure

    1) the volatility in this market began in late November; we designate the Korean crisis

    period from 25 November 1997 to 31 December 1997. The Thai crisis in equity markets

    dates from 10 June 1997 to 29 August 1997 (Billio and Pelizzon, 2003; Rigobon, 2003).

    The crisis periods are shown as the narrow shaded areas in each of the panels of Figure

    1.

    Table 1 gives data sources and some descriptive statistics for the returns series. The

    rst panel is for the entire sample, showing that ltering does not remove the non-

    normality in the data and motivating the use of a structural GARCH model for the

    ltered residuals to captured volatility clustering and fat tails. The following four panels

    give the crisis periods chronologically, conrming that, in general, the volatility of returns

    rises when a market is in crisis.

    Our modelling strategy depends on the preservation of higher order dynamics in the

    VAR residuals, so we tested the returns series for dependence and nonlinearity before and

    after VAR ltering. Following Kyrtsou and Serletis (2006) and Bekiros and Georgoutsos

    (2008a), we applied the BDS test (Brock et al. 1996) for time-based dependence (in-

    dependent and identically distributed observations), the Tsay (1986) test for quadratic

    9Data sources are listed in the notes to Table 1. Before estimation we removed all observations whereany market was not trading. This reduced the number of observations in the sample period from 3951to 3607.

  • 16

    serial dependence in means, the Engle (1982) LM test for nonlinearity in the variance,

    and the Hinich (1982) bispectrum test for nonlinearity and Gaussianity. All tests reject

    the nulls of independence and linearity before and after VAR ltering suggesting that

    only linear dependence and the common shock have been removed.10 Table 2 reports sig-

    nicance levels (p-values) for the Tsay, Engle and Hinich tests and Table 3 shows results

    for the BDS (Brock et al. 1996).

    6. Estimation results

    Tables 4 to 6 gives the results of applying the model of Section 3 to the Asian dataset.

    We estimate using quasi-maximum likelihood techniques (QML) via numerical methods in

    Ox. Figure 2 sets out graphical evidence for model t, showing the standardized residuals

    for each market and Table 2 reports p-values for tests for linear and non-linear dependence

    and Gaussianity. The model accounts for much of the conditional heteroskedasticity,

    skewness and kurtosis of the original ltered series seen in Figure 1, although some non-

    normality remains as evidenced by the Hinich test results, and we observe a few large

    outliers associated with specic market events.11 Testing failed to nd any signicant

    ARCH e¤ects in any of the standardized residuals series. The Tsay and Hinich tests

    for linearity in means are not rejected at the 5% level for Hong Kong, Indonesia and

    Thailand standardized residuals but the results are somewhat weaker for Korea. Table

    3 shows p-values for the BDS test which fail to reject pure randomness for all but the

    Indonesian residuals. We view these results with caution given the problems with test size

    and interpretation that can arise when applying this test to the residuals of a non-linear

    model. (See Brooks and Heravi 1999, and Brooks and Henry 2000.)

    10We also tted a multivariate Mackey-Glass model (Kyrtsou and Labys 2006) as an alternative to theVAR(1) but found no substantial di¤erence to the ltered residuals and so selected the simpler VAR(1)model. Results for the Mackey-Glass lter are available from the authors on request.11The large outlier in March 1996 in the Hong Kong series shows the signicant falls in this market

    and through the region due to concerns over China. A number of events appear to be linked with theoutliers for the Indonesian returns, including the opening of the market to full foreign ownership inOctober 1993, general regional volatility in April 1998, the Bali bombings in October 2002 and politicaluncertainty combined with major earthquakes in May 2006. The September 11 attacks show up in theoutlier in the Korean series and a panic over currency regulations in December 2006 creates an outlierin the Thai series. Model estimation is robust to the removal of these large outliers. We do not reportresults separately here but they are available from the authors on request.

  • 17

    Table 4 shows the tranquil period coe¢ cient estimates. There are signicant linkages

    between a number of the equity markets. The reported coe¢ cients show the impact of

    returns from the markets in the table row on the corresponding column market return.

    Reading down each column, the returns to the Hong Kong index exhibit a signicant

    positive relationship with returns in Indonesia, (0:086) and Korea (0:296): Indonesian

    returns are also signicantly a¤ected by Hong Kong (0:103) while the Korean returns are

    positively related to Indonesias (0:148) but negatively related to Hong Kongs (�0:125)

    during periods of tranquility. The Thai market appears to import a positive impact from

    all three neighbors in the tranquil period, but does not inuence the other markets (as

    evident in the last row of Table 4).

    Hypersensitivity occurs when the connections between domestic markets and foreign

    markets change during a domestic crisis period (Table 5). The coe¢ cients in this table

    represent the impact due to crises in markets in the column headings but felt via the

    returns from (non-crisis) markets in the rows, hence hypersensitivity. Only one linkage

    is statistically signicant and positive in Table 5. This represents positive hypersensitivity

    of the Hong Kong market to Indonesian returns (0:814) during the Hong Kong crisis.

    Two more linkages are signicant and negative. Korean returns covaried negatively with

    Indonesian returns during the Korean crisis (�0:753) and that Hong Kong returns varied

    negatively with Korean returns during the Hong Kong crisis, (�0:751).

    The negative coe¢ cients represent an interesting addition to the literature, in that

    they suggest that during periods of crisis, links between two markets may move in either

    direction. This is consistent with Forbes and Rigobon (2002) who nd a fall in conditional

    correlation in many instances, and with the network literature where reduced linkages

    during crises are also consistent with lower correlation.

    Contagion occurs when a local market is a¤ected by crisis in other countries. Table 6

    shows the strength of these e¤ects. In this table contagion e¤ects arise from crises in the

    row markets and impact on returns to the (non-crisis) column market. Results show that

    Indonesia experienced contagion from Korea during the Korean crises (0:727). During the

    Hong Kong crisis (rst row of the table), Korea experienced signicant positive contagion

  • 18

    e¤ects from Hong Kong (0:665) while Thailand was impacted negatively by Hong Kong

    returns (�0:504):

    Table 7 provides the parameter estimates for the GARCH behavior of the underlying

    shocks. In each of the cases there is a small positive and signicant constant and signif-

    icant ARCH and GARCH e¤ects. The combined ARCH and GARCH parameters sum

    close to one in each case.

    A likelihood ratio test of the hypothesis that all hypersensitivity and contagion dum-

    mies are zero yields a test statistic of 78:24 � �224 which has a p-value close to zero.

    In summary we nd evidence for shifts in the relationships between the equity mar-

    kets of Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea and Thailand during the crisis period, but these

    e¤ects are not uniform in direction or signicance across countries and crises. In terms

    of strengthening e¤ects, the Hong Kong crisis had a large impact on regional markets,

    generating signicant contagion in Korea but creating a weakening link with Thailand,

    where correlation fell (Table 6). During the Hong Kong crisis in October 1997, the Hong

    Kong market also became less sensitive to news from Korea but more sensitive to news

    from Indonesia (Table 5). Combining the results reported in Tables 5 and 6, it is appar-

    ent that the Korean crisis later that year transmitted additional turbulence to Indonesia,

    but at the same time returns from Indonesia became signicantly less inuential for the

    Korean market, possibly suggesting that the domestic turmoil both created trouble for

    the neighboring market and drowned out feedback from outside. We observe this same

    e¤ect in relation to Hong Kong and Korea. During the Hong Kong crisis Korea receives

    signicant positive contagion (0:665) but Korean returns are dampened into Hong Kong

    (�1:981 in Table 5). By way of contrast, the signs on the contagion and hypersensitiv-

    ity parameters connecting Hong Kong and Indonesia indicate an amplication in both

    directions: the Hong Kong crisis had signicant positive contagion e¤ects on Indonesia

    (0:103 in Table 6) but returns in Indonesia also had a signicant positive hypersensitivity

    e¤ect on Hong Kong during the Hong Kong crisis (0:814 in Table 5). The linkages be-

    tween markets clearly take a number of forms and their interaction displays a complexity

    previously not disentangled.

  • 19

    6.1. Variance decomposition

    The rst panel of Table 8 gives the tranquil period decomposition at one step ahead,

    with 5th and 95th quantile measures.12 We use these results to allocate the shocks to their

    source market. In each case, we label the shock that makes the greatest contribution to

    volatility in each of the tranquil-period decompositions as the own-country shock.13 The

    columns in the table refer to the volatility in each asset (or portfolio), and the rows to the

    contributing sources of shock. Own-country shocks contribute at least 80% of forecast

    error variance in each case. The maximum impact from another country at the mean is

    17% (the link from Korean shocks to the Hong Kong market). The nal column in Table

    8 gives the variance decompositions for the equally weighted portfolio which also account

    for covariance between the returns. In the tranquil period, Korean and Indonesian shocks

    are dominant, at 39% and 31% of the total whereas Hong Kong and Thailand contribute

    around 15% each.

    The second panel of Table 8 shows the variance decompositions relating to links due to

    hypersensitivity during crisis periods.14 There are substantial changes from the tranquil

    period. The contribution of domestic shocks is diminished and the impact of Indonesia

    increases commensurately. For Hong Kong, Indonesian shocks dominate the local e¤ect,

    contributing half the forecast error variance. For the equally-weighted portfolio, results

    show an increased contribution of 30 percentage points from Indonesia (60%) and about

    5 percentage points more from Hong Kong. The contribution from Korea is reduced,

    most likely due to the changing link between Indonesia and Korea.

    During an external crisis, contagion links also create dramatic changes. The third

    panel of Table 8 shows that the contribution of domestic market shocks to the one-step-

    ahead variance decomposition is reduced under foreign crises compared with the tranquil

    period for three of the four markets. Change is most dramatic for Indonesia where the

    contribution from domestic shocks drops by 57 percentage points to a mean contribution

    12The variance decomposition is constructed for all t possible conditionings in the sample. A histogramof these outcomes gives the mean and quantiles reported in Table 8.13The results at 5 steps ahead conrm our classication.14All insignicant parameters are set to zero when variance decompositions and impulse response

    functions are computed.

  • 20

    of 42%; contagion from Korea (46%) and Hong Kong (12%) account for this. The contri-

    bution of the domestic shock for Hong Kong falls by about 10 percentage points to 71%

    in favour of an increase in Korean contribution to 26%. The contribution of domestic

    shocks for Korea decreases by about 17 percentage points, and the inuence of Hong

    Kong rises from less than 1% to 15%. There is no real change in the Thai decomposition.

    Hence, Hong Kong and Korean shocks are clearly important in all countries apart from

    Thailand. This is also evident in the portfolio results, where the contribution of Hong

    Kong increases by 7 percentage points to 22% and the Korean contribution increases to

    57% due to contagion e¤ects. However, there are falls in the percentage contributions of

    Indonesia and Thailand to portfolio variance.

    6.2. Impulse response functions

    Figure 3 presents impulse responses in the variance of the equally weighted portfolio

    to unit (one standard deviation) shocks from Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea and Thailand

    respectively. The left column shows the impulse response in the tranquil period, and

    the right column shows the responses with contagion e¤ects. Using the unconditional

    (sample) portfolio variance as a basis for calculation, a 0.1 increase in portfolio variance

    on the vertical axis is approximately equal to a 0.6 percentage point (60 basis point)

    increase in annualized portfolio volatility.

    A structural shock associated with Hong Kong (Panel A) in the tranquil period is

    the smallest of those investigated here, and takes about two months to dissipate half the

    initial impact. When we account for contagion, however, the e¤ect of a one standard

    deviation shock is to raise variance by a factor of ve over the tranquil period, with

    increases persisting above the initial tranquil period impact for well over three months.

    Patterns for impulses to structural shocks from Indonesia (Panel B) are remarkably

    di¤erent. The initial impact of a one standard deviation shock in the tranquil period

    is much larger and the distribution of responses is also more dispersed. By contrast,

    contagion e¤ects are small in this case, so that unlike Hong Kong, impulse responses for

    shocks from Indonesia in tranquil and contagion periods are alike though the dispersion

    is greater during the contagion period.

  • 21

    The impact of Korean shocks (Panel C) in the tranquil period is greater than for Hong

    Kong, but not so large as for the Indonesian case already discussed. During the tranquil

    period there are statistically signicant linkages with all the other countries in the sample,

    as shown in Table 4. The contagion e¤ects are substantial, with the size of the initial

    shock in the external crisis scenario being ve-fold the tranquil period shock. Half of this

    impact has dissipated by 45 days after the shock, but some e¤ect is still present nearly

    a year after the initial shock. As a result of the lack of linkages from Thailand to other

    markets, the impulse responses to shocks originating from Thailand (Panel D) are small

    and do not change between the tranquil and contagion periods.

    Overall, the largest contributors to volatility are the Hong Kong and Korean crises.

    Shocks from these events increase portfolio variance by between around ve times and

    persist for a number of months.

    Another way to view contagion is via impulse responses on specic covariances. Im-

    pulse responses of the equally-weighted portfolio variance average over the whole co-

    variance matrix and can inform diversied investors, whereas responses of individual

    covariances detail bivariate market links rather than averaging across them, measuring

    contagion directly. This technique can also give a breakdown of the way interrelationships

    changes during a crisis.

    Figure 4 shows impulse responses of four of the six covariances to a one standard devi-

    ation shock from the Hong Kong market. The array of di¤erent reactions is illuminating.

    Panel A shows the impulse response for the Hong Kong-Indonesia covariance. We see

    that the tranquil market link between the Hong Kong and Indonesian markets is weak,

    and a shock has a very small impact, whereas the additional contagion period channel

    raises covariance responsiveness by a factor of 10 and takes around two months for half

    the e¤ect to dissipate. In Panel B, the impulse to the Hong Kong-Korea covariance is ac-

    tually negative under normal market conditions, but crisis contagion shifts the covariance

    to a strong and persistent positive. By contrast, Panel C sets out the impulse response

    to the covariance between Hong Kong and Thailand. Whereas the correlation between

    these markets is normally positive and Hong Kong shocks tended to raise the conditional

  • 22

    covariance, during the crisis the links between Thailand and the rest of the region weak-

    ened, and the response of the covariance shifts from positive to negative. Finally, Panel

    D shows an example of crisis-driven changes at a secondary level. The Hong Kong shock

    is irrelevant to the Indonesia-Korea covariance in tranquil markets but contagion creates

    additional transmissions amongst the markets, increasing the covariance from zero to

    0.12, even though neither of these markets is the source of the news. The remaining co-

    variances (Indonesia-Thailand and Korea-Thailand) were very marginally a¤ected by the

    Hong Kong shock, both responding slightly more negatively when a¤ected by contagion.

    The impulses of the covariances reveal some of the complexity of the linkages which

    occur during crises. Assessing the e¤ects of shocks originating in one country is com-

    plicated by both the crisis market transmissions to other markets via contagion and the

    potential for changes in the reaction of the crisis market to information from other mar-

    kets via hypersensitivity. However, there are also discernible secondary level e¤ects so

    that non crisis countries experience increased covariances with each other even though

    the e¤ects are not a direct impact of the news from the crisis country. These e¤ects are

    realizations of the interrelatedness of the system.

    7. Conclusion

    We develop a model which contributes a renement to the taxonomy of crises: we

    distinguish between hypersensitivity and contagion. A market which is in crisis may

    transmit that crisis towards other markets, denoted contagion, and it may simulta-

    neously become more or less sensitive to the e¤ects of shocks from non-crisis markets,

    denoted hypersensitivity. This distinction has some importance in policy discussions.

    A country experiencing a crisis is likely to be concerned primarily with preventing the

    impact of hypersensitivity while countries which are not themselves in crisis are more

    concerned to prevent the spread of the crisis via contagion e¤ects. Policy design for crisis

    prevention and management need to be incentive compatible with the actively operating

    links. This suggests that authorities require a substantial degree of discretion to actively

    manage crises, as their characteristics vary greatly in terms of the directions and strength

    of changes in linkages from tranquil to crisis periods.

  • 23

    In particular, our results suggest that during the Asian crisis, the crisis countries

    themselves had at best weak incentives to slow the spread of turbulence, while the nearby

    markets had reason to look for protection either via domestic regulation or through

    international policy coordination.

    The modelling framework separates hypersensitivity and contagion based on a mul-

    tivariate GARCH framework with regimes and exogenously dened crisis periods. An

    advantage is that structural parameters can be identied from the reduced form. Unlike

    past work, which has relied on arbitrary restrictions to classify the sources of unobserv-

    able structural shocks, we use variance decompositions to label the structural shocks and

    connect them to source markets. This approach enables an economic interpretation of

    risk transmission in tranquil and crisis periods.

    Applying this model to four Asian equity markets during the East Asian crisis period

    of 1997-1998, we observe statistically signicant contagion links and hypersensitivity. Im-

    portantly, these changes are not always positive. The Thai market, for example becomes

    more detached from shocks from near neighbors during their crises. Hong Kong trans-

    mitted its crisis via contagion e¤ects to both Korea and Thailand, while at the same time

    becoming more sensitive to news from Indonesia and less sensitive to news from Korea.

    Similarly, during the Korean crisis, Korea transmitted its crisis via contagion to Indonesia

    but simultaneously became less sensitive to Indonesian market news. From an investment

    perspective, decomposing the portfolio volatility of an equally-weighted portfolio of the

    four equity assets identies the redistribution of sources of turbulence away from home

    market and towards outside. Impulse response analysis shows the increasing dominance

    of Korean and Hong Kong shocks during the crisis, while variance decompositions conrm

    this e¤ect and also highlight heightened sensitivity to Indonesian sourced shocks during

    crises in other countries. An examination of the cross market linkages revealed the variety

    of e¤ects operating during the crisis period.

    This new framework and application contribute a breakdown of the directional ef-

    fects of the relationship between asset markets during crisis. The model has a number

    of similarities with the recent theoretical network literature on linkages between nancial

  • 24

    institutions, where those institutions care about inow from, and outow to, counter-

    parties; see Allen and Babus (2008) for an overview. Future work linking the empirical

    framework developed in this paper and network theory should provide insights into the

    credit crunch of 2007-2008.

    Acknowledgments

    We thank Andrea Cipollini, John Geweke, Tony Hall, Gordon Menzies, Adrian Pa-

    gan, Peter Phillips, Remco Zwinkels and participants at the 2007 INFINITI Conference,

    Trinity College Dublin, the 2008 NCER Frontiers in Financial Econometrics Workshop,

    Queensland University of Technology Brisbane, and an anonymous referee for helpful com-

    ments. Part of this paper was written while Thorp was a Visiting Scholar at Cambridge

    Endowment for Research in Finance, University of Cambridge. Thorp acknowledges the

    support of ARC DP0877219.

    Appendix A. Two-asset illustration

    Here we present a two-dimensional illustration of the main features of the model and

    dynamics.

    The tranquil period model for VAR-ltered returns for asset markets 1 and 2, denoted

    by y1t and y2t; is:

    y1t = b12y2t + g11;t"1t (A.1)

    y2t = b21y1t + g22;t"2t; (A.2)

    which can be extended for crisis periods to

    y1t = b12y2t + bs;12D1ty2t + bc;12D2ty2t + g11;t"1t (A.3)

    y2t = b21y1t + bs;21D2ty1t + bc;21D1ty1t + g22;t"2t; (A.4)

    where the binary dummy variables, D1t and D2t take the value 1 during periods of crisis

    experienced in y1t and y2t respectively, and 0 otherwise. Data in the crisis periods provide

  • 25

    the extra information needed to identify the contagion parameters. For the rest of the ex-

    ample, we work with the simpler tranquil period model. The matrix of contemporaneous

    market linkages is normalized on the diagonal to give,

    B =

    264 1 �b12�b21 1

    375 (A.5)and

    B�1 : = A =

    264 a11 a12a21 a22

    375 : (A.6)The GARCH processes on "i in this case are:264 g211t 0

    0 g222t

    375 = diag8>:264 1 2

    375+264 �11 00 �22

    375264 u21t�1u22t�1

    3759>=>;

    +

    264 �11 00 �22

    375264 g211t�1 0

    0 g222t�1

    375 : (A.7)so that gii;t"it = uit:

    To estimate the simple model structure in (A.1) and (A.2) we need to account for the

    covariance between yit and ujt and the identication of structural parameters, and we

    resolve both estimation issues by working with the reduced-form covariance matrix.

    For two assets, the reduced form covariance matrix vechHt = Avvecd (Gt) from

    equation (12) can be expressed as

    266664H11;t

    H21;t

    H22t

    377775 =266664

    a211 a212

    a11a21 a12a22

    a221 a222

    377775�8>:264 1 2

    375+264 �11u21t�1�22u

    22t�1

    375+264 �11g211t�1�22g

    222t�1

    3759>=>; (A.8)

  • 26

    From (13) above we can write

    �t�1 � �t�1 = Aut�1 �Aut�1

    =

    264 (a11u1t�1 + a12u2t�1)2(a21u1t�1 + a22u2t�1)

    2

    375264 �21t�1�22t�1

    375 =264 a211 a212a221 a

    222

    375264 u21t�1u22t�1

    375264 a211 a212a221 a

    222

    375�1 264 �21t�1

    �22t�1

    375 =264 u21t�1u22t�1

    375 (A.9)using the assumption that the structural shocks are independent so that cross products

    in u1t and u2t can be set to zero. From equation (14)

    ht�1 =

    264 H11t�1H22t�1

    375 =264 a211 a212a221 a

    222

    375264 g211t�1g222t�1

    375264 a211 a212a221 a

    222

    375�1 264 H11t�1

    H22t�1

    375 =264 g211t�1g222t�1

    375 (A.10)If we rewrite Ht in vech (�) form and dene the requisite transformation of the A matrix

    as Av then

    266664H11;t

    H21;t

    H22t

    377775 =266664

    a211 a212

    a11a21 a12a22

    a221 a222

    377775

    8>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>:

    264 1 2

    375+264 �11 00 �22

    375264 a211 a212a221 a

    222

    375�1 264 �21t�1

    �22t�1

    375+

    264 �11 00 �22

    375264 a211 a212a221 a

    222

    375�1 264 H11t�1

    H22t�1

    375

    9>>>>>>>>=>>>>>>>>;(A.11)

    A.1. Dynamics

    The proportion of the forecast error variance for return to domestic market one, y1;

  • 27

    that is due to structural shock "1 is

    V D1;1jt =a211g

    21;t+1jt

    a211g21;t+1jt + a

    212g

    22;t+1jt

    (A.12)

    and due to structural shock "2 is

    V D1;2jt =a212g

    22;t+1jt

    a211g21;t+1jt + a

    212g

    22;t+1jt

    (A.13)

    The proportion of portfolio error variance for an equally weighted portfolio includes the

    impact of diversication, and error sourced in "1 would be represented by the following

    expression,

    V Dp;1 =�g21;t+1jt

    �a211 + 2a21a11 + a

    221

    ��=�

    g21;t+1jt�a211 + 2a21a11 + a

    221

    �+ g22;t+1jt

    �a212 + 2a12a22 + a

    222

    ��: (A.14)

    Impulse responses in this case are

    Et

    �@w0Ht+1w

    @"21;t

    �= Et

    8>:@264(1=2)2 [g21;t+1jt (a211 + 2a21a11 + a221)

    +g22;t+1jt (a212 + 2a12a22 + a

    222)]

    375 =@"21;t9>=>;

    = (1=2)2�a211 + 2a21a11 + a

    221

    �Et

    (@g21;t+1jt@"21;t

    )(A.15)

    which creates a recursion in the structural parameters so that for an initial shockEt�"21;t�=q

    Et�"21;t�= 1 in period t;

    g21;t+1jt = 1 + �1u21;t + �1g

    21;t (A.16)

    Et

    (@g21;t+1jt@"21;t

    )= �1g

    21;t (A.17)

    and

    Et

    �@w0Ht+1w

    @"21;t

    �= (1=2)2

    �a211 + 2a21a11 + a

    221

    ��1g

    21;t: (A.18)

  • 28

    For the covariance conditional impulse response functions we compute

    Et

    �@Ht+1@"21;t

    �ij

    = a21a11�1g21;t: (A.19)

    References

    Akhigbe, A., Madura, J., 2001. Why do contagion e¤ects vary among bank failures?Journal of Banking and Finance 25, 657-680.

    Allen, F., Babus, A., 2008. Networks in nance. Working Paper 08-07 Wharton FinancialInstitutions Centre.

    Allen, F., Gale, D., 2000. Financial contagion. Journal of Political Economy 108, 1-33.

    Bae, K-H., Karolyi, G.A., Stulz, R.M., 2005. A new approach to measuring nancialcontagion. Review of Financial Studies 16, 717-763.

    Baig, T., Goldfajn, I.,1999. Financial market contagion in the Asian crisis. IMF Sta¤Papers 46, 167-195.

    Baur, D., Schulze, N., 2005. Co-exceedances in nancial markets: A quantile regressionanalysis of contagion. Emerging Markets Review 6, 21-43.

    Bekiros, S. D., Georgoutsos, D. A., 2008a. Non-linear dynamics in nancial asset returns:The predictive power of the CBOE volatility index. European Journal of Finance 14,397-408.

    Bekiros, S. D., Georgoutsos, D. A., 2008b. The extreme-value dependence of Asia-Pacicequity markets. Journal of Multinational Financial Management 18, 197-208.

    Billio, M., Caporin, L., 2005. Multivariate Markov switching dynamic conditional correla-tion GARCH representations for contagion analysis. Statistical Methods and Applications14/2, 145-161.

    Billio, M., Pelizzon, L., 2003. Contagion and interdependence in stock markets: Havethey been misdiagnosed? Journal of Economics and Business 55, 405-426.

    Brock, W.A., Dechert, A., Lebaron, B., Scheinkman, J.A., 1996. A test for independencebased on the correlation dimension. Econometric Reviews 15, 197-235.

    Brooks, C., Henry, O.T., 2000. Can portmanteau model nonlinearity tests serve as generalmodel mis-specication diagnostics? Evidence from symmetric and asymmetric GARCHmodels. Economics Letters 67, 245-51.

    Brooks, C., Heravi, S., 1999. The e¤ect of mis-specied GARCH lters on the nitesample distribution of the BDS test. Computational Economics 13, 147-62.

  • 29

    Brusco, S., Castiglionesi, F., 2007. Liquidity coinsurance, moral hazard and nancialcontagion. Journal of Finance 62, 2275-2302.

    Candelon, B., Piplack, J., Straetmans, S., 2008. On measuring synchronization of bullsand bears: The case of East Asia. Journal of Banking and Finance 32, 1022-1035.

    Caporale, G., Cipollini, A., Spagnolo, N., 2005. Testing for contagion: A conditionalcorrelation analysis. Journal of Empirical Finance 12, 476-489.

    Castiglionesi, F., 2007. Financial contagion and the role of the central bank. Journal ofBanking and Finance 31, 31-101.

    Corsetti, G., Pericoli, M., Sbracia, M., 2005. Some contagion, some interdependence:More pitfalls in tests of nancial contagion. Journal of International Money and Finance24, 1177-1199.

    Diamond, D.W., Dybvig, P.H., 1983. Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. Journalof Political Economy 91, 401-419.

    Dornbusch, R., Park, Y. C., Claessens, S., 2000. Contagion: Understanding how itspreads. The World Bank Observer 15, 177-197.

    Dungey, M., Martin, V.L., 2007. Unravelling nancial market linkages during crises.Journal of Applied Econometrics 22, 89-119.

    Eglo¤, D., Lieppold, M., Vanini, P., 2007. A simple model of credit contagion. Journal ofBanking and Finance 31, 2475-2492.

    Engle, R.F., 1982. Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity with estimates of thevariance of United Kingdon ination. Econometrica 50, 987-1007.

    Engle, R.F., Ng, V.G., 1993. Measuring and testing the impact of news on volatility.Journal of Finance 48, 1749-1778.

    Favero, C., Giavazzi, F., 2002. Is the international propagation of nancial shocks non-linear? Evidence from the ERM. Journal of International Economics 57, 231-46.

    Forbes, K., Rigobon, R., 2002. No contagion, only interdependence: Measuring stockmarket co-movements. Journal of Finance 57, 2223-2261.

    Freixas, X., Parigi, B.M., Rochet, J-C., 2000. Systemic risk, interbank relations, andliquidity provision by the central bank. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 32, 611-638.

    Furne, C., 2003. Interbank exposure: Quantifying the risk of contagion. Journal ofMoney, Credit and Banking 35, 111-128.

    Gallant, A.R., Rossi, P.E., Tauchen, G., 1993. Nonlinear dynamic structures. Economet-rica 61, 871-907.

    Giesecke, K., Weber, S., 2004. Cyclical correlations, credit contagion and portfolio loss.Journal of Banking and Finance 28, 3009-3036.

    Hasman, A., Samartín, M., 2008. Information acquisition and nancial contagion. Journalof Banking and Finance 32, 2136-2147.

  • 30

    Hinich, M.J., 1982. Testing for Gaussianity and linearity of a stationary time series.Journal of Times Series Analysis 3, 169-176.

    Kaminsky, G., Reinhart, C., 2002. Financial markets under stress. Journal of Develop-ment Economics 69, 451-470.

    Kodres, L., Pritsker, M., 2002. A rational expectations model of nancial contagion.Journal of Finance 57, 769-799.

    Kyrtsou, C., Labys, W., 2006. Evidence for chaotic dependence between US ination andcommodity prices. Journal of Macroeconomics 28, 256-266.

    Kyrtsou, C., Serletis, A., 2006. Univariate tests for nonlinear structure. Journal of Macro-economics 28, 154-168.

    Lin, W-L., 1997. Impulse response function for conditional volatility in GARCH Models.Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 15, 15-25.

    Markwat, T., Kole, E., van Dijk, D., 2009. Contagion as a domino e¤ect in global stockmarkets. Journal of Banking and Finance 33, 1996-2012.

    Pesaran, H., Pick, A., 2007. Econometric issues in the analysis of contagion. Journal ofEconomic Dynamics and Control 31, 1245-1277.

    Pavlova, A., Rigobon, R., 2007. The role of portfolio constraints in the internationalpropagation of shocks. Review of Economic Studies, forthcoming.

    Rigobon, R., 2003. On the measurement of the international propagation of shocks: Isthe transmission stable? Journal of International Economics 61, 261-283.

    Rigobon, R., Sack, B., 2004. Impact of monetary policy on asset prices. Journal of Mon-etary Economics 51, 1553-1575.

    Rothenberg, T., 1971. Identication in parametric models. Econometrica 39, 577-591.

    Tsay, R. S., 1986. Nonlinearity tests for time series. Biometrika 73, 461-466.

    Yang, J., Zhou, Y., Wang, Z., 2009. The stock-bond correlation and macroeconomicconditions: One and a half centuries of evidence. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33,670-680.

    Yuan, K., 2005. Asymmetric price movements and borrowing constraints: A rationalexpectations equilibrium model of crises, contagion, and confusion. Journal of Finance60, 379-411.

  • 31

    Figure 1: Time Series of Filtered Daily Returns to Asian Equity Price Indices,

    January 1992 to January 2007.

    -20

    -10

    0

    10

    20

    A. Hong Kong returns

    -40

    -30

    -20

    -10

    0

    10

    20

    30

    B. Indonesia returns

    -20

    -10

    0

    10

    20

    C. Korea returns

    -16

    -12

    -8

    -4

    0

    4

    8

    12

    16

    D. Thailand returns

    1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    Note: Each series is the residuals from a VAR(1). Grey bars indicate the period designated

    as crisis period in each country. Data sources are described in Table 1.

  • 32

    Figure 2: Standardized residuals from tted SGARCH model,

    January 1992 to January 2007.

    -8

    -4

    0

    4

    8

    A. Hong Kong standardized residual

    -12

    -8

    -4

    0

    4

    8

    B. Indonesia standardized residual

    -10.0

    -7.5

    -5.0

    -2.5

    0.0

    2.5

    5.0

    C. Korea standardized residual

    -12

    -8

    -4

    0

    4

    8

    D. Thailand standardized residual

    1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    Note: Each series is the structural residual from the tted SGARCH model standardized

    by the tted conditional structural standard deviation for the relevant market and time period

  • 33

    Figure 3: Impulse Response Functions of Equally Weighted Portfolio Variance toa Standard Deviation Shock for Periods of Tranquility and Contagion

    Tranquil Period ContagionA. Hong Kong sourced shock

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    B. Indonesian sourced shock

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    C. Korean sourced shock

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    1.2

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    1.2

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    D. Thai sourced shock

    0.00

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.10

    0.12

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    0.00

    0.02

    0.04

    0.060.08

    0.10

    0.12

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    Note: Vertical axes show the absolute increase in the daily variance of an equally-weightedportfolio of the equity indices n-days after a one standard deviation structural shock from eachequity market. Impulse response functions are calculated conditioning on volatility at everytime = t in the sample. The dashed lines represent the 5th and 95th quantiles of the empiricaldistribution of the conditional impulse responses and the solid line represents the median.

  • 34

    Figure 4: Impulse Response Functions of Market Covariances toa Standard Deviation Shock from Hong Kong for Periods of Tranquility and Contagion

    Tranquil Period ContagionA. Hong Kong-Indonesia

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    B. Hong Kong-Korea

    -0.10.00.10.20.30.40.50.6

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    -0.10.00.10.20.30.40.50.6

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    C. Hong Kong-Thailand

    -0.1

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    -0.1

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    D. Indonesia-Korea

    -0.1

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    1 33 65 97 129 161 193 225

    days

    Note: Vertical axes show the absolute increase in the daily covariance between selected equityindices n-days after a one standard deviation structural shock from Hong Kong equity market.Impulse response functions are calculated conditioning on volatility at every time = t in thesample. The dashed lines represent the 5th and 95th quantiles of the empirical distribution of

    the conditional impulse responses and the solid line represents the median.

  • 35

    Table 1:Descriptive Statistics for Equity Returns: Tranquil Period and Crisis Periods

    Hong Kong Indonesia Korea Thailand(HK) (IN) (KO) (TH)

    Total Period: 2 January 1992-9 January 2007Mean 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Std dev. 1.606 2.456 2.169 1.885Skew 0.016 -1.436 -0.127 0.168Kurt 13.354 40.469 12.977 9.500J-B p-val 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

    Thai crisis: 10 June 1997 - 29 August 1997Mean -0.061 -0.642 -0.053 -0.500Std dev. 1.662 2.487 1.062 3.832Skew -0.390 -0.857 -0.102 0.079Kurt 4.942 4.128 2.751 3.190J-B p-val 0.001 0.007 0.884 0.930

    Hong Kong crisis: 27 October 1997 - 17 November 1997Mean -0.353 -0.168 -0936 -0.450Std dev. 6.767 5.155 4.936 3.776Skew 0.700 1.010 0.210 0.271Kurt 5.046 3.631 2.325 2.204J-B p-val 0.129 0.226 0.810 0.734

    Korean crisis: 25 November 1997 - 31 December 1997Mean 0.137 -0.723 -1.191 -1.002Std dev. 2.435 7.671 10.916 2.942Skew -0.485 -0.331 0.333 0.288Kurt 2.959 5.737 2.010 2.969J-B p-val 0.612 0.016 0.477 0.841

    Indonesian crisis: 5 January 1998 to 27 February 1998Mean -0.019 -1.599 0.496 1.166Std dev. 3.982 11.600 5.193 5.310Skew 0.496 -0.527 -0.461 -0.034Kurt 4.360 4.538 2.976 3.4168J-B p-val 0.112 0.069 0.520 0.872

    Note: Returns are computed as percentage log changes in the price indices for Hong Kong(Hang Seng HNGKNGI), Indonesia (Jakarta Composite JAKCOMP), Korea (Korea

    Composite KORCOMP) and Thailand (Bangkok SET BNGKSET) using daily series fromDatastream, translated to US dollars before returns are computed. Sample runs from 2

    January 1992 to 9 January 2007 but observations where there is a zero return from any seriesare removed before de-meaning, leaving 3607 days. Returns are ltered using a VAR(1) in thereturns and the contemporaneous daily 3-month US Treasury Bill secondary market mid-rate

    (FRTBS3M).

  • 36

    Table 2:Tests for linearity and Gaussianity in returns, VAR residuals and standardized

    SGARCH residuals.

    p� valuesTsay (1986) Engle (1982) Hinich (1982)8 lags 8 lags 210 lattice points

    H0 Linarity in mean no ARCH Linearity GaussianityReturns, ritHong Kong 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Indonesia 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Korea 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Thailand 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

    VAR residuals, yitHong Kong 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Indonesia 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Korea 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Thailand 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

    Standardized residuals, "itHong Kong 0.544 0.789 0.279 0.002Indonesia 0.050 0.150 0.939 0.006Korea 0.020 0.780 0.005 0.000Thailand 0.654 0.086 0.093 0.000

    Note: Table reports p-values for Tsay (1986) test for linearity in means, Engle (1982) test forARCH e¤ects, and Hinich (1982) bispectrum test for linearity and Gaussianity, for returns

    (log changes in US dollar values of equity price indexes), residuals from VAR(1) ltering of thereturns series including contemporaneous values of the 3 month US T-bill, and the

    standardized structural residuals from the SGARCH model tted to the VAR residuals. Forcomputation of test statistics see Kyrtsou and Serletis (2006).

  • 37

    Table 3:BDS tests for departures from randomness in returns, VAR residuals and standardized

    SGARCH residuals.

    p� valuesReturns, rit VAR residuals, yit Standardized residuals, "it

    distance; " 0:5� � 1:5� 2� 0:5� � 1:5� 2� 0:5� � 1:5� 2�Hong Kongm = 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.583 0.607 0.909 0.494m = 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.611 0.734 0.958 0.513m = 4 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.394 0.495 0.721 0.673m = 5 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.266 0.292 0.398 0.959m = 6 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.105 0.144 0.212 0.652Indonesiam = 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.0002 0.006m = 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.002m = 4 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.0004 0.005m = 5 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.001 0.001 0.004 0.025m = 6 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.003 0.003 0.013 0.050Koream = 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.101 0.101 0.106 0.187m = 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.106 0.109 0.137 0.378m = 4 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.128 0.159 0.283 0.712m = 5 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.147 0.249 0.401 0.796m = 6 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.150 0.383 0.552 0.916Thailandm = 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.031 0.135 0.575 0.980m = 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.131 0.350 0.908 0.599m = 4 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.319 0.596 0.981 0.603m = 5 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.418 0.664 0.982 0.710m = 6 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.251 0.495 0.751 0.952

    Note: Table reports p-values for BDS (Brock et al. 1996) tests for pure randomness in returns(log changes in US dollar values of equity price indexes), residuals from VAR(1) ltering of the

    returns series including contemporaneous values of the 3 month US T-bill, and thestandardized structural residuals from the SGARCH model tted to the VAR residuals. Theparameter " sets the benchmark for comparing distances between consecutive pairs of points

    in the test sample and the embedding dimension, m, sets the number of pairs in eachcomparison set. See Brock et al. (1996) for details.

  • 38

    Table 4:Parameter Estimation Results: Tranquil Periods

    TO market i (yi)Hong Kong Indonesia Korea Thailand(HK) (IN) (KO) (TH)

    FROM market j; (yj)Hong Kong bi;HK 0.103 -0.125 0.263

    (0.003) (0.050) (0.000)Indonesia bi;IN 0.086 0.148 0.152

    (0.001) (0.006) (0.000)Korea bi;KO 0.296 0.009 0.098

    (0.000) (0.812) (0.031)Thailand bi;TH 0.032 0.034 0.024

    (0.533) (0.430) (0.642)

    Note: Parameter estimates for the model B�Yt= ut; where (B+BcDt +DtBs)Yt = B�Y with

    BcDt +DtBs representing the linkages present in crisis periods. Estimation is by QML overdaily ltered returns to equity market indices, sampling 6 January 1992 to 9 January 2007.

    P-values are in brackets.

  • 39

    Table 5:Parameter Estimation Results: Hypersensitivity During Crises in market i

    TO market i (yi) when Dit = 1Hong Kong Indonesia Korea Thailand(HK) (IN) (KO) (TH)

    FROM market j; (yj)Hong Kong bs;i;HK -2.050 -1.981 0.424

    (0.191) (0.246) (0.451)Indonesia bs;i;IN 0.814 -0.753 0.238

    (0.000) (0.031) (0.168)Korea bs;i;KO -0.751 -0.636 -0.687

    (0.013) (0.505) (0.415)Thailand bs;i;TH 0.475 1.346 0.927

    (0.234) (0.341) (0.467)

    Note: Parameter estimates for the model B�Yt= ut; where (B+BcDt +DtBs)Yt = B�Y with

    BcDt +DtBs representing the linkages present in crisis periods. Each period of crisis isidentied using an indicator variable Di;t which is one during the crisis in home country i andzero otherwise. Hypersensitivity (indicated by subscript s) is given by the parameter bs;ij ineach equation, operating when Dit = 1; measuring the additional impact of foreign shocksduring a domestic crisis. The relevance of each instance of hypersensitivity is tested by thesignicance of the parameters bs;ij. Estimation is by QML over daily ltered returns to equity

    market indices, sampling 6 January 1992 to 9 January 2007. P-values are in brackets.

  • 40

    Table 6:Parameter Estimation Results: Contagion During Crises in market j:

    TO market i (yi)Hong Kong Indonesia Korea Thailand(HK) (IN) (KO) (TH)

    FROM market j; (yj) when Djt = 1Hong Kong bc;i;HK 0.180 0.665 -0.504

    (0.263) (0.003) (0.021)Indonesia bc;i;IN 0.128 0.145 -0.127

    (0.266) (0.488) (0.569)Korea bc;i;KO -0.153 0.727 -0.007

    (0.276) (0.001) (0.917)Thailand bc;i;TH -0.175 -0.051 -0.092

    (0.128) (0.654) (0.229)

    Note: Parameter estimates for the model B�Yt= ut; where (B+BcDt +DtBs)Yt = B�Y with

    BcDt +DtBs representing the linkages present in crisis periods. Each period of crisis isidentied using an indicator variable Di;t which is one during the crisis in home country i andzero otherwise. Contagion (indicated by subscript c) is modelled as the additional impact onasset markets in home country i during a crisis in foreign country j; given by the parameterbs;ij in each equation, operating when Djt = 1: The relevance of each instance of contagion istested by the signicance of the parameters bc;ij. Estimation is by QML over daily lteredreturns to equity market indices, sampling 6 January 1992 to 9 January 2007. P-values are in

    brackets.

  • 41

    Table 7:GARCH parameter estimates

    Structural Shocksi Hong Kong Indonesia Korea Thailand

    Constant i 0.029 0.070 0.079 0.115(0.036) (0.020) (0.002) (0.037)

    ARCH �i 0.089 0.181 0.126 0.171(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.003)

    GARCH � i 0.897 0.809 0.859 0.797(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

    Note: Parameter estimates for the conditional covariance matrix of the structural shocks,Gt = diag[ + � (ut�1 � ut�1)] + �Gt�1;where is a 4� 1 vector of constants, � is a 4� 4 diagonal

    matrix of ARCH coe¢ cients and � is a 4� 4 diagonal matrix of GARCH coe¢ cients.Estimation is by QML over daily ltered returns to equity market indices, sampling 6 January

    1992 to 9 January 2007. P-values are in brackets.

  • 42

    Table 8:Mean Conditional Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (One Step Ahead)

    "i Hong Kong Indonesia Korea Thailand portfolio

    TranquilHong Kong 80.38 1.10 0.81 5.04 15.56

    [61.89 - 95.19] [0.12-3.42] [0.20-2.39] [1.56-11.82] [4.81-38.40]Indonesia 3.06 98.74 1.99 5.33 30.88

    [0.44-9.16] 96.30-99.83] [0.39-5.53] [0.91-15.27] [10.79-63.63]Korea 16.59 0.16 97.21 4.76 39.47

    [4.06-33.57] [0.03-0.42] [93.06-99.23] [1.20-11.59] [16.11-64.30]Thailand 0.00 0.00 0.00 84.87 14.09

    [0.00-0.00] [0.00-0.00] [0.00-0.00] [69.44-94.98] [4.32-29.80]

    HypersensitivityHong Kong 31.26 1.32 1.83 6.25 21.29

    [7.71-65.00] [0.15-64.09] [0.42-5.63] [1.85-14.93] [4.72-48.28]Indonesia 55.99 98.23 32.44 20.56 60.36

    [24.38-86.43] [95.10-99.74] [11.17-65.11] [4.72-50.79] [29.49-88.91]Korea 12.75 0.45 65.73 0.27 4.06

    [3.60-26.13] [0.08-1.17] [33.99-87.28] [0.07-0.66] [1.05-9.22]Thailand 0.00 0.00 0.00 72.91 14.29

    [0.00-0.00] [0.00-0.00] [0.00-0.00] [44.37-91.19] [3.50-31.46]

    ContagionHong Kong 70.91 11.75 15.29 1.19 22.01

    [48.07-91.80] [02.79-32.02] [4.75-37.83] [0.35-12.88] [7.80-50.37]Indonesia 3.28 41.92 3.23 4.06 16.34

    [0.51-9.65] [17.21-75.20] [0.68-9.05] [0.67-11.67] [4.44-40.63]Korea 25.81 46.33 81.49 5.56 57.17

    [47.22-47.98] [19.60-71.35] [58.57-93.48] [1.35-13.57] [289.63-79.18]Thailand 0.00 0.00 0.00 89.19 4.47

    [0.00-0.00] [0.00-0.00] [0.00-0.00] [76.38-96.88] [1.30-9.73]

    Note: Conditional one-step ahead error variance decompositions, computed for individualassets and an equally-weighted portfolio of market indices. Rows show the mean of empiricalhistogram of the conditional variance decompositions, conditioning on each standard deviation

    gii;t in the sample, and gures in square brackets are the 5th and 95th quantiles.