QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS - Doing Business · entrepreneur in Italy needs to follow 16...

of 37 /37
THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Vol. CXVII February 2002 Issue 1 THE REGULATION OF ENTRY* SIMEON DJANKOV RAFAEL LA PORTA FLORENCIO LOPEZ-DE-SILANES ANDREI SHLEIFER We present new data on the regulation of entry of start-up rms in 85 countries. The data cover the number of procedures, of cial time, and of cial cost that a start-up must bear before it can operate legally. The of cial costs of entry are extremely high in most countries. Countries with heavier regulation of entry have higher corruption and larger unof cial economies, but not better quality of public or private goods. Countries with more democratic and limited governments have lighter regulation of entry. The evidence is inconsistent with public interest theories of regulation, but supports the public choice view that entry regulation bene ts politicians and bureaucrats. I. INTRODUCTION Countries differ signi cantly in the way in which they regu- late the entry of new businesses. To meet government require- ments for starting to operate a business in Mozambique, an entrepreneur must complete 19 procedures taking at least 149 business days and pay US$256 in fees. To do the same, an entrepreneur in Italy needs to follow 16 different procedures, pay US$3946 in fees, and wait at least 62 business days to acquire the * We thank Tatiana Nenova, Ekaterina Trizlova, and Lihong Wang for able research assistance, and three anonymous referees, Abhijit Banerjee, Richard Caves, Edward Glaeser, Roumeen Islam, Simon Johnson, Lawrence Katz, David Laibson, Guy Pfeffermann, and seminar participants at George Mason University and the University of Maryland at College Park for helpful comments. The collection of data for this paper was nanced by the World Bank’s Research Advisory Group and the World Development Report 2002: Building Institutions for Markets. An appendix describing country data is available from the authors on request. © 2002 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 2002 1

Embed Size (px)

Transcript of QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS - Doing Business · entrepreneur in Italy needs to follow 16...

  • THE

    QUARTERLY JOURNALOF ECONOMICS

    Vol. CXVII February 2002 Issue 1

    THE REGULATION OF ENTRY*

    SIMEON DJANKOVRAFAEL LA PORTA

    FLORENCIO LOPEZ-DE-SILANESANDREI SHLEIFER

    We present new data on the regulation of entry of start-up rms in 85countries. The data cover the number of procedures, ofcial time, and ofcial costthat a start-up must bear before it can operate legally. The ofcial costs of entryare extremely high in most countries. Countries with heavier regulation of entryhave higher corruption and larger unofcial economies, but not better quality ofpublic or private goods. Countries with more democratic and limited governmentshave lighter regulation of entry. The evidence is inconsistent with public interesttheories of regulation, but supports the public choice view that entry regulationbenets politicians and bureaucrats.

    I. INTRODUCTION

    Countries differ signicantly in the way in which they regu-late the entry of new businesses. To meet government require-ments for starting to operate a business in Mozambique, anentrepreneur must complete 19 procedures taking at least 149business days and pay US$256 in fees. To do the same, anentrepreneur in Italy needs to follow 16 different procedures, payUS$3946 in fees, and wait at least 62 business days to acquire the

    * We thank Tatiana Nenova, Ekaterina Trizlova, and Lihong Wang for ableresearch assistance, and three anonymous referees, Abhijit Banerjee, RichardCaves, Edward Glaeser, Roumeen Islam, Simon Johnson, Lawrence Katz, DavidLaibson, Guy Pfeffermann, and seminar participants at George Mason Universityand the University of Maryland at College Park for helpful comments. Thecollection of data for this paper was nanced by the World Bank’s ResearchAdvisory Group and the World Development Report 2002: Building Institutionsfor Markets. An appendix describing country data is available from the authors onrequest.

    © 2002 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute ofTechnology.The Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 2002

    1

  • necessary permits. In contrast, an entrepreneur in Canada cannish the process in two days by paying US$280 in fees andcompleting only two procedures.

    In this paper we describe the required procedures governingentry regulation, as well as the time and the cost of followingthese procedures, in 85 countries. We focus on legal requirementsthat need to be met before a business can ofcially open its doors,the ofcial cost of meeting these requirements, and the minimumtime it takes to meet them if the government does not delay theprocess. We then use these data to evaluate economic theories ofregulation. Our work owes a great deal to De Soto’s [1990] path-breaking study of entry regulation in Peru. Unlike De Soto, welook at the ofcial requirements, ofcial cost, and ofcial time—and do not measure corruption and bureaucratic delays thatfurther raise the cost of entry.

    Pigou’s [1938] public interest theory of regulation holds thatunregulated markets exhibit frequent failures, ranging from mo-nopoly power to externalities. A government that pursues socialefciency counters these failures and protects the public throughregulation. As applied to entry, this view holds that the govern-ment screens new entrants to make sure that consumers buy highquality products from “desirable” sellers. Such regulation reducesmarket failures such as low quality products from y-by-nightoperators and externalities such as pollution. It is “done to ensurethat new companies meet minimum standards to provide a goodor service. By being registered, new companies acquire a type ofofcial approval, which makes them reputable enough to engagein transactions with the general public and other businesses”[SRI 1999, p. 14]. The public interest theory predicts that stricterregulation of entry, as measured by a higher number of proce-dures in particular, should be associated with socially superioroutcomes.

    The public choice theory [Tullock 1967; Stigler 1971; Peltz-man 1976] sees the government as less benign and regulation associally inefcient. It comes in two avors. In Stigler’s [1971]theory of regulatory capture, “regulation is acquired by the in-dustry and is designed and operated primarily for its benet.”Industry incumbents are able to acquire regulations that createrents for themselves, since they typically face lower informationand organization costs than do the dispersed consumers. In thistheory the regulation of entry keeps out the competitors andraises incumbents’ prots. Because stricter regulation raises bar-

    2 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • riers to entry, it should lead to greater market power and protsrather than benets to consumers.

    A second strand of the public choice theory, which we call thetollbooth view, holds that regulation is pursued for the benet ofpoliticians and bureaucrats [McChesney 1987; De Soto 1990;Shleifer and Vishny 1998]. Politicians use regulation both tocreate rents and to extract them through campaign contributions,votes, and bribes. “An important reason why many of these per-mits and regulations exist is probably to give ofcials the power todeny them and to collect bribes in return for providing the per-mits” [Shleifer and Vishny 1993, p. 601]. The capture and toll-booth theories are closely related, in that they both address rentcreation and extraction through the political process. The capturetheory emphasizes the benets to the industry, while the toll-booth theory stresses those to the politicians even when theindustry is left worse off by regulation.

    In principle, the collection of bribes in exchange for releasefrom regulation can be efcient. In effect, the government canbecome an equity holder in a regulated rm. In practice, however,the creation of rents for the bureaucrats and politicians throughregulation is often inefcient, in part because the regulators aredisorganized, and in part because the policies they pursue toincrease the rents from corruption are distortionary. The analogyto tollbooths on a highway is useful. Efcient regulation may callfor one toll for the use of a road, or even no tolls if the operationof the road is most efciently nanced through general tax reve-nues. In a political equilibrium, however, each town throughwhich the road passes might be able to erect its own tollbooth.Toll collectors may also block alternative routes so as to force thetrafc onto the toll road. For both of these reasons, political tollcollection is inefcient.

    In the tollbooth theory the regulation of entry enables theregulators to collect bribes from the potential entrants and servesno social purpose. “When someone has nally made the decisionto invest, he then is subjected to some of the worst treatmentimaginable. . . In a few cases this treatment consists of outrightextortion: presenting the investor with insurmountable delays orrepeated obstacles unless he makes a large payoff . . .” [WorldBank 1999, p. 10]. More extensive regulation should be associatedwith socially inferior outcomes, particularly corruption.

    We assess the regulation of entry around the world from theperspective of these theories by addressing two broad sets of

    3THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • questions. First, what are the consequences of the regulation ofentry, and in particular, who gets the rents? If the regulation ofentry serves the public interest, it should be associated withhigher quality of goods, fewer damaging externalities, andgreater competition. Public choice theory, in contrast, predictsthat stricter regulation is most clearly associated with less com-petition and higher corruption.

    A second question we examine to distinguish the alternativetheories of regulation is which governments regulate entry? Thepublic interest model predicts that governments whose interestsare more closely aligned with those of the consumers, which wethink of as the more representative and more limited govern-ments, should ceteris paribus regulate entry more strictly. Incontrast, the public choice model predicts that the governmentsleast subject to popular oversight should pursue the strictestregulations, to benet themselves and possibly the incumbentrms. Knowing who regulates thus helps to discriminate amongthe theories.

    Our analysis of exhaustive data on entry regulation in 85countries leads to the following conclusions. The number of pro-cedures required to start up a rm varies from the low of 2 inCanada to the high of 21 in the Dominican Republic, with theworld average of around 10. The minimum ofcial time for such astart-up varies from the low of 2 business days in Australia andCanada to the high of 152 in Madagascar, assuming that thereare no delays by either the applicant or the regulators, with theworld average of 47 business days. The ofcial cost of followingthese procedures for a simple rm ranges from under 0.5 percentof per capita GDP in the United States to over 4.6 times per capitaGDP in the Dominican Republic, with the worldwide average of47 percent of annual per capita income. For an entrepreneur,legal entry is extremely cumbersome, time-consuming, and ex-pensive in most countries in the world.

    In a cross section of countries, we do not nd that stricterregulation of entry is associated with higher quality products,better pollution records or health outcomes, or keener competi-tion. But stricter regulation of entry is associated with sharplyhigher levels of corruption, and a greater relative size of theunofcial economy. This evidence favors public choice over thepublic interest theories of regulation.

    In response, a public interest theorist could perhaps arguethat heavy regulation in some countries is a reection of both

    4 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • signicant market failures and the unavailability of alternativemechanisms of addressing them, such as good courts or freepress. In addition, corruption and a large unofcial economy maybe inadvertent consequences of benevolent regulation, and hencecannot be used as evidence against the public interest view. Suchinadvertent consequences might obtain as a side effect of screen-ing out bad entrants [Banerjee 1997; Acemoglu and Verdier2000], or simply as a result of a well-intended but misguidedtransplant of rich-country regulations into poor countries. Be-cause of this logic, the question of which countries regulate entrymore heavily may be better suited conceptually to distinguish thealternative theories.

    We nd that the countries with more open access to politicalpower, greater constraints on the executive, and greater politicalrights have less burdensome regulation of entry—even control-ling for per capita income—than do the countries with less rep-resentative, less limited, and less free governments. The percapita income control is crucial for this analysis because it couldbe argued that richer countries have both better governments anda lower need for the regulation of entry, perhaps because theyhave fewer market failures or better alternative ways of dealingwith them. The fact that better governments regulate entry less,along with the straightforward interpretation of the evidence oncorruption and the unofcial economy, point to the tollbooththeory: entry is regulated because doing so benets theregulators.

    The next section describes the sample. Section III presentsour basic results on the extent of entry regulation around theworld. Section IV asks who gets the rents from regulation. SectionV presents the main results on which governments regulate.Section VI concludes.

    II. DATA

    A. Construction of the Database

    This paper is based on a new data set, which describes theregulation of entry by start-up companies in 85 countries in 1999.We are interested in all the procedures that an entrepreneurneeds to carry out to begin legally operating a rm involved inindustrial or commercial activity. Specically, we record all pro-cedures that are ofcially required of an entrepreneur in order to

    5THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • obtain all necessary permits and to notify and le with all requi-site authorities. We also calculate the ofcial costs and timenecessary for the completion of each procedure under normalcircumstances. The study assumes that the information is readilyavailable and that all governmental bodies function efcientlyand without corruption.

    We collect data on entry regulation using all available writ-ten information on start-up procedures from government publi-cations, reports of development agencies such as the World Bankand USAID, and government web pages on the Internet. We thencontact the relevant government agencies to check the accuracy ofthe data. Finally, for each country we commission at least oneindependent report on entry regulation from a local law rm, andwork with that rm and government ofcials to eliminate dis-agreements among them.

    We use ofcial sources for the number of procedures, time,and cost. If ofcial sources are conicting or the laws are ambigu-ous, we follow the most authoritative source. In the absence ofexpress legal denitions, we take the government ofcial’s reportas the source. If several ofcial sources have different estimatesof time and cost, we take the median. Absent ofcial estimates oftime and cost, we take the estimates of local incorporation law-yers. If several unofcial (e.g., a private lawyer) sources havedifferent estimates, we again take the median.

    Our countries span a wide range of income levels and politi-cal systems. The sample includes fourteen African countries, nineEast Asian countries including China and Vietnam, three SouthAsian countries (India, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka), all Central andEastern European countries except for Albania and some of theformer Yugoslav republics, eight former Soviet Union republicsand Mongolia, ten Latin American countries, two Caribbeancountries (Dominican Republic and Jamaica), six Middle Easterncountries (Egypt, Israel, Jordan, Lebanon, Morocco, and Tunisia),and all major developed countries.

    We record the procedures related to obtaining all the neces-sary permits and licenses, and completing all the required in-scriptions, verications, and notications for the company to belegally in operation. When there are multiple ways to beginoperating legally, we choose the fastest in terms of time. In somecountries, entrepreneurs may not bother to follow ofcial proce-dures or bypass them by paying bribes or hiring the services of“facilitators.” An entrepreneur in Georgia can start up a company

    6 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • after going through 13 procedures in 69 business days and paying$375 in fees. Alternatively, he may hire a legal advisory rm thatcompletes the start-up process for $610 in three business days. Inthe analysis, we use the rst set of numbers. We do so because weare primarily interested in understanding the structure of ofcialregulation.

    Regulations of start-up companies vary across regions withina country, across industries, and across rm sizes. For concrete-ness, we focus on a “standardized” rm, which has the followingcharacteristics: it performs general industrial or commercial ac-tivities, it operates in the largest city1 (by population), it is ex-empt from industry-specic requirements (including environmen-tal ones), it does not participate in foreign trade and does nottrade in goods that are subject to excise taxes (e.g., liquor, to-bacco, gas), it is a domestically owned limited liability company,2

    its capital is subscribed in cash (not in-kind contributions) and isthe higher of (i) 10 times GDP per capita in 1999 or (ii) theminimum capital requirement for the particular type of businessentity, it rents (i.e., does not own) land and business premises, ithas between 5 and 50 employees one month after the commence-ment of operations all of whom are nationals, it has turnover of upto 10 times its start-up capital, and it does not qualify for invest-ment incentives. Although different legal forms are used in dif-ferent countries to set up the simplest rm, to make comparisonswe need to look at the same form.

    Our data almost surely underestimate the cost and complex-ity of entry.3 Start-up procedures in the provinces are oftenslower than in the capital. Industry-specic requirements addprocedures. Foreign ownership frequently involves additionalverications and procedures. Contributions in kind often requireassessment of value, a complex procedure that depends on thequality of property registries. Finally, purchasing land can bequite difcult and even impossible in some of the countries of thesample (for example, in the Kyrgyz Republic).

    1. In practice, the largest city coincides with the capital city except in Aus-tralia (Melbourne), Brazil (Sao Paulo), Canada (Toronto), Germany (Frankfurt),Kazakhstan (Almaty), the Netherlands (Amsterdam), South Africa (Johannes-burg), Turkey (Istanbul), and the United States (New York).

    2. If the Company Law allows for more than one privately owned businessform with limited liability, we choose the more popular business form amongsmall companies in the country.

    3. The World Economic Forum [2001] surveys business people on how impor-tant administrative regulations are as an obstacle to new business. Our threemeasures are strongly positively correlated with these subjective assessments.

    7THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • B. Denitions of Variables

    We use three measures of entry regulation: the number ofprocedures that rms must go through, the ofcial time requiredto complete the process, and its ofcial cost. In the public interesttheory, a more thorough screening process requires more proce-dures and demands more time. In the public choice theory, moreprocedures and longer delays facilitate bribe extraction (tollboothview) or make entry less attractive to potential competitors (cap-ture view).

    Theoretical predictions regarding our measure of cost areambiguous. A benevolent social planner who wants to spendsignicant resources on screening new entrants may choose tonance such activity with broad taxes rather than with the directfees that we measure, leading to low costs as we measure them. Acorrupt regulator may also want to set fees low in order to raisehis own bribe income if, for example, fees are veriable andcannot be expropriated by the regulator.4 In contrast, higher feesare unambiguously desirable as a tool to deter entry under thecapture theory. Because of these ambiguities, we present statis-tics on cost mainly to describe an important attribute of regula-tion and not to discriminate among theories.

    We keep track of all the procedures required by law to starta business. A separate activity in the start-up process is a “pro-cedure” only if it requires the entrepreneur to interact with out-side entities: state and local government ofces, lawyers, audi-tors, company seal manufacturers, notaries, etc. For example, alllimited liability companies need to hold an inaugural meeting ofshareholders to formally adopt the Company Articles and Bylaws.Since this activity involves only the entrepreneurs, we do notcount it as a procedure. Similarly, most companies hire a lawyerto draft their Articles of Association. However, we do not countthat as a procedure unless the law requires that a lawyer beinvolved. In the same vein, we ignore procedures that the entre-preneur can avoid altogether (e.g., reserving exclusive rights overa proposed company name until registration is completed) or thatcan be performed after business commences.5 Finally, when ob-

    4. Shleifer and Vishny [1993] distinguish corruption with theft from corrup-tion without theft. In the latter case, the regulator must remit the ofcial fee tothe Treasury, and therefore has no interest in that fee being high.

    5. In several countries, our consultants advised us that certain procedures,while not required, are highly recommended, because failure to follow them mayresult in signicant delays and additional costs. We collected data on these

    8 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • taining a document requires several separate procedures involv-ing different ofcials, we count each as a procedure. For example,a Bulgarian entrepreneur receives her registration certicatefrom the Company Registry in Soa, and then has to pay theassociated fee at an ofcially designated bank. Even though bothactivities are related to “obtaining the registration certicate,”they count as two separate procedures in the data.

    To measure time, we collect information on the sequence inwhich procedures are to be completed and rely on ofcial guresas to how many business days it takes to complete each proce-dure. We ignore the time spent to gather information, and as-sume that all procedures are known from the very beginning. Wealso assume that procedures are taken simultaneously wheneverpossible, for maximum efciency. Since entrepreneurs may havetrouble visiting several different institutions within the same day(especially if they come from out-of-town), we set the minimumtime required to visit an institution to be one day.6 Anotherjustication for this approach is that the relevant ofces some-times open for business only briey: both the Ministry of Econ-omy and the Ministry of Justice in Cairo open for business onlybetween 11 a.m. and 2 p.m.

    We estimate the cost of entry regulation based on all identi-able ofcial expenses: fees, costs of procedures and forms, pho-tocopies, scal stamps, legal and notary charges, etc. All costgures are ofcial and do not include bribes, which De Soto [1990]has shown to be signicant for registration. Setup fees often varywith the level of start-up capital. As indicated, we report the costsassociated with starting to operate legally a rm with capitalequivalent to the larger of (i) ten times per capita GDP in 1999 or(ii) the minimum capital requirement stipulated in the law. Wehave experimented with other capital levels and found our resultsto be robust.

    Theoretical predictions for the cost of entry regulation areambiguous. As an alternative measure, we consider only the

    procedures, but did not include them in the variables presented here because wewanted to stick to the mandatory criterion. We have rerun the regressions dis-cussed below including these highly recommended procedures. The inclusion doesnot have a material impact on the results.

    6. In the calculation of time, when two procedures can be completed on thesame day in the same building, we count that as one day rather than two(following the urgings of ofcials in several countries, where several ofces arelocated in the same building). Our results are not affected by this particular wayof computing time.

    9THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • component of the cost that goes to the government, which in thesample averages about half the total cost. The results for this costvariable are generally weaker than for the total out-of-pocketcost, but go in the same direction. Our basic cost estimates alsoignore the opportunity cost of the entrepreneur’s time and theforgone prots associated with bureaucratic delay. To addressthis concern, we calculate a “full cost” measure, which adds up theofcial expenses and an estimate of the value of the entrepre-neur’s time, valuing his time at the country’s per capita incomeper working day. We report this number below, and have repli-cated the analysis using it as a measure of cost. The resultsobtained using this cost measure are very similar to those usingthe raw data on time and cost, and hence are not presented.

    Table I lists typical procedures associated with setting up arm in our sample. The procedures are further divided by theirfunction: screening (a residual category, which generally aims tokeep out “unattractive” projects or entrepreneurs), health andsafety, labor, taxes, and environment. The basic procedure instarting up a business, present everywhere, is registering withthe Companies’ Registry. This can take more than one procedure;sometimes there is a “preliminary license” and a “nal” license.Combined with that procedure, or as a separate procedure, is thecheck for uniqueness of the proposed company name. Add-onprocedures comprise the requirements to notarize the CompanyDeeds, to open a bank account and deposit of start-up capital, andto publish a notication of the company’s establishment in anofcial or business paper. Additional screening procedures thatinclude obtaining different certicates and ling with agenciesother than the Registry may add up to 97 days in delays, as is thecase in Madagascar. Another set of basic screening procedures,present in almost every country in the data set, covers certainmandatory municipal procedures, registrations with statisticalofces and with Chambers of Commerce and Industry (or respec-tive Ministries). In the Dominican Republic these procedures takeseven procedures and fourteen days. There is large cross-countryvariation in terms of the number, time, and cost of screeningprocedures as the Company Registry performs many of thesetasks automatically in the most efcient countries but the entre-preneur does much of the legwork in the less efcient ones.

    Additional procedures appear in four areas. The rst coverstax-related procedures, which require seven procedures andtwenty days in Madagascar. The second is labor regulations,

    10 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • TABLE ILIST OF PROCEDURES FOR STARTING UP A COMPANY

    This table provides a list of common procedures required to start up acompany in the 85 countries of the sample.

    1. Screening procedures- Certify business competence- Certify a clean criminal record- Certify marital status- Check the name for uniqueness- Notarize company deeds- Notarize registration certicate- File with the Statistical Bureau- File with the Ministry of Industry and Trade, Ministry of the Economy, or the

    respective ministries by line of business- Notify municipality of start-up date- Obtain certicate of compliance with the company law- Obtain business license (operations permit)- Obtain permit to play music to the public (irrespective of line of business)- Open a bank account and deposit start-up capital- Perform an ofcial audit at start-up- Publish notice of company foundation- Register at the Companies Registry- Sign up for membership in the Chamber of Commerce or Industry or the Regional

    Trade Association2. Tax-related requirements

    - Arrange automatic withdrawal of the employees’ income tax from the company payrollfunds

    - Designate a bondsman for tax purposes- File with the Ministry of Finance- Issue notice of start of activity to the Tax Authorities- Register for corporate income tax- Register for VAT- Register for state taxes- Register the company bylaws with the Tax Authorities- Seal, validate, rubricate accounting books

    3. Labor/social security-related requirements- File with the Ministry of Labor- Issue employment declarations for all employees- Notarize the labor contract- Pass inspections by social security ofcials- Register for accident and labor risk insurance- Register for health and medical insurance- Register with pension funds- Register for Social Security- Register for unemployment insurance- Register with the housing fund

    4. Safety and health requirements- Notify the health and safety authorities and obtain authorization to operate from the

    Health Ministry- Pass inspections and obtain certicates related to work safety, building, re,

    sanitation, and hygiene5. Environment-related requirements

    - Issue environmental declaration- Obtain environment certicate- Obtain sewer approval- Obtain zoning approval- Pass inspections from environmental ofcials- Register with the water management and water discharge authorities

    11THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • which require seven procedures and 21 days in Bolivia. The thirdarea is health and safety regulations, which demand ve proce-dures and 21 business days in Malawi. The nal area coverscompliance with environmental regulations, which take two pro-cedures and ten days in Malawi if all goes well.

    Figures I and II describe the number, time, and cost of theprocedures needed to begin operating legally in New Zealand andFrance, respectively. New Zealand’s streamlined start-up processtakes only three procedures and three days. The entrepreneurmust rst obtain approval for the company name from the web-site of the Registrar of Companies, and then apply online forregistration with both the Registrar of Companies and the taxauthorities.

    In contrast, the process in France takes 15 procedures and 53days. To begin, the founder needs to check the chosen companyname for uniqueness at the Institut National de la PropriétéIndustrielle (INPI). He then needs the mayor’s permit to use hishome as an ofce. (If the ofce is to be rented, the founder mustsecure a notarized lease agreement.) The following documentsmust then be obtained, each from a different authority: proof of a

    FIGURE IStart-up Procedures in New Zealand

    Procedures are lined up sequentially on the horizontal axis and described in thetext box. The time required to complete each procedure is described by the heightof the bar and measured against the left scale. Cumulative costs (as a percentageof per capita (GDP) are plotted using a line and measured against the right scale.

    12 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • clean criminal record, an original extract of the entrepreneur’scerticate of marital status from the City Hall, and a power ofattorney. The start-up capital is then deposited with a notarybank or Caisse des Dépôts, and is blocked there until proof ofregistration is provided. Notarization of the Articles of Associa-tion follows. A notice stating the location of the headquartersofce is published in a journal approved for legal announcements,and evidence of the publication is obtained. Next, the founderregisters four copies of the articles of association at the local taxcollection ofce. He then les a request for registration with theCentre de Formalités des Entreprises (CFE) which handles dec-larations of existence and other registration-related formalities.The CFE must process the documents or return them in case therequest is incomplete. The CFE automatically enters the com-pany information in the Registre Nationale des Entreprises(RNE) and obtains from the RNE identication numbers: numeroSIRENE (Système Informatique pour le Répertoire des Entre-prises), numero SIRET (Système Informatique pour le Répertoiredes Etablissements), and numero NAF (Nomenclature des Activi-tées Francaises). The SIRET is used by, among others, the tax

    FIGURE IIStart-up Procedures in France

    Procedures are lined up sequentially on the horizontal axis and described in thetext box. The time required to complete each procedure is described by the heightof the bar and measured against the left scale. Cumulative costs (as a percentageof per capita GDP) are plotted using a line and measured against the right scale.

    13THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • authorities. The RNE also publishes a notice of the companyformation in the ofcial bulletin of civil and commercial an-nouncements. The rm then obtains a proof of registration form“K-bis,” which is effectively its identity card. To start legal opera-tions, the entrepreneur completes ve additional procedures: in-form the post ofce of the new enterprise, designate a bondsmanor guarantee payment of taxes with a cash deposit, unblock thecompany’s capital by ling with the bank a proof of registration(K-bis), have the rm’s ledgers and registers initialed, and le forsocial security. The magazine L’Entreprise comments: “To be surethat the le for the Company Registry is complete, many promot-ers check it with a counselor’s service, which costs FF200 in Paris(about US$30). But there’s always something missing, and mostentrepreneurs end up using a lawyer to complete the procedure.”

    III. BASIC RESULTS

    Table II describes all the variables used in this study. TableIII presents the basic information from our sample. Countries areranked in ascending order rst by the total number of entryprocedures, then by the time it takes to complete them, andnally by the cost of entry. We classify each procedure as one ofve types: safety and health, environmental, tax, labor, and aresidual category which we label “screening,” whose purpose un-der the public interest theory is to weed out the undesirableentrepreneurs. We then compute and report the total number ofprocedures and their breakdown into our ve categories for eachcountry. We also report the minimum number of business daysthat are ofcially required to comply with entry regulations, thecosts arising from the ofcial fees, and the total costs whichimpute the entrepreneur’s time (as a fraction of GDP per capita).Finally, we take averages by income level and report t-testscomparing the regulation of entry across income groups.

    The data show enormous variation in entry regulation acrosscountries. The total number of procedures ranges from 2 in Can-ada to 21 in the Dominican Republic and averages 10.48 for thewhole sample. Very few entry regulations cover tax and laborissues. The worldwide average number of labor and tax proce-dures are 1.94 and 2.02, respectively. Procedures involving envi-ronmental issues and safety and health matters are even rarer(0.14 and 0.34 procedures on average, respectively). Instead,much of what governments do to regulate entry falls into the

    14 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • category of screening procedures. The worldwide average numberof such procedures facing a new entrant is 6.04.

    The number of procedures is highly correlated with both thetime and cost variables (see Table VI). The correlation of the (log)number of procedures with (log) time is 0.83 and with (log) cost is0.64. Translated into economic terms, this means that entrepre-neurs pay a steep price in terms of fees and delays in countriesthat make intense use of ex ante screening. For example, com-pleting 19 procedures demands 149 business days and 111.5percent of GDP per capita in Mozambique. In Italy the completionof 16 procedures takes up 62 business days and 20 percent of GDPper capita. The Dominican Republic is in a class of its own:completing its 21 procedures requires 80 business days and feesof at least 4.63 times per capita GDP. These gures are admit-tedly extreme within the sample, yet meeting the ofcial entryrequirements in the average sample country requires roughly 47days and fees of 47 percent of GDP per capita.

    When we aggregate time and out-of-pocket costs into anaggregate cost measure, the results for some countries becomeeven more extreme. The world average full cost measure rises to66 percent of per capita GDP, but varies from 1.7 percent of percapita GDP for New Zealand to 4.95 times per capita GDP in theDominican Republic.

    Panel B of Table III reports averages of the total number ofprocedures and its components, time and cost by quartiles of percapita GDP in 1999. Two patterns emerge. First, the cost-to-per-capita-GDP ratio decreases uniformly with GDP per capita. Theaverage cost-to-per-capita-GDP ratio for countries in the topquartile of per capita GDP (“rich countries”) is 10 percent andrises to 108 percent in countries in the bottom quartile of percapita GDP. This pattern merely reects the fact that the incomeelasticity of fees (in log levels) is about 0.2. Second, countries inthe top quartile of per capita GDP require fewer procedures andtheir entrepreneurs face shorter delays in starting a legal busi-ness than those in the remaining countries.7 The total number ofprocedures in an average rich country is 6.8 which is signicantlylower than the rest-of-sample average of 11.8 (t-statistics are

    7. One objection to this nding is that entrepreneurs in rich countries mightface more postentry regulations than they do in poor countries. We have data onone aspect of postentry regulation, namely the regulation of labor markets (seeDjankov et al. [2001a]). The numbers of entry and of labor market regulations arepositively correlated across countries, contrary to this objection.

    15THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • TA

    BL

    EII

    TH

    EV

    AR

    IAB

    LE

    S

    Thi

    sta

    ble

    desc

    ribe

    sth

    eva

    riab

    les

    coll

    ecte

    dfo

    rth

    e85

    cou

    ntri

    esin

    clud

    edin

    our

    stud

    y.T

    her

    stco

    lum

    ngi

    ves

    the

    nam

    eof

    the

    vari

    able

    .The

    seco

    nd

    colu

    mn

    desc

    ribe

    sth

    eva

    riab

    lean

    dpr

    ovid

    esth

    eso

    urce

    sfr

    omw

    hic

    hit

    was

    coll

    ecte

    d.

    Var

    iabl

    eD

    escr

    ipti

    on

    Nu

    mbe

    rof

    proc

    edu

    res

    Th

    enu

    mbe

    rof

    diff

    eren

    tpr

    oced

    ure

    sth

    ata

    star

    t-up

    has

    toco

    mpl

    yw

    ith

    inor

    der

    toob

    tain

    ale

    gal

    stat

    us,i

    .e.,

    tost

    art

    oper

    atin

    gas

    ale

    gal

    enti

    ty.S

    ourc

    e:A

    uth

    ors’

    own

    calc

    ula

    tion

    s.S

    afet

    y&

    Hea

    lth

    The

    num

    ber

    ofdi

    ffere

    ntsa

    fety

    and

    heal

    thpr

    oced

    ures

    that

    ast

    art-

    upha

    sto

    com

    ply

    wit

    hto

    star

    top

    erat

    ing

    asa

    lega

    lent

    ity.

    Sour

    ce:A

    utho

    rs’o

    wn

    calc

    ulat

    ions

    .E

    nvir

    onm

    ent

    Th

    enu

    mbe

    rof

    diff

    eren

    ten

    viro

    nm

    enta

    lpr

    oced

    ure

    sth

    ata

    star

    t-up

    has

    toco

    mpl

    yw

    ith

    tost

    art

    oper

    atin

    gas

    ale

    gal

    enti

    ty.S

    ourc

    e:A

    uth

    ors’

    own

    calc

    ulat

    ion

    s.T

    axes

    Th

    enu

    mbe

    rof

    diff

    eren

    tta

    xpr

    oced

    ures

    that

    ast

    art-

    upha

    sto

    com

    ply

    wit

    hto

    star

    top

    erat

    ing

    asa

    lega

    len

    tity

    .So

    urce

    :Aut

    hors

    ’ow

    nca

    lcul

    atio

    ns.

    Lab

    orT

    he

    num

    ber

    ofdi

    ffer

    ent

    labo

    rpr

    oced

    ures

    that

    ast

    art-

    up

    has

    toco

    mpl

    yw

    ith

    tost

    art

    oper

    atin

    gas

    ale

    gal

    enti

    ty.S

    ourc

    e:A

    utho

    rs’o

    wn

    calc

    ulat

    ions

    .S

    cree

    ning

    Th

    enu

    mbe

    rof

    diff

    eren

    tst

    eps

    that

    ast

    art-

    upha

    sto

    com

    ply

    wit

    hin

    orde

    rto

    obta

    ina

    regi

    stra

    tion

    cert

    ica

    teth

    atar

    eno

    tas

    soci

    ated

    wit

    hsa

    fety

    and

    heal

    this

    sues

    ,the

    envi

    ronm

    ent,

    taxe

    s,or

    labo

    r.S

    ourc

    e:A

    utho

    rs’o

    wn

    calc

    ulat

    ion

    s.T

    ime

    Th

    eti

    me

    itta

    kes

    toob

    tain

    lega

    lst

    atus

    toop

    erat

    ea

    rm

    ,in

    busi

    ness

    days

    .Aw

    eek

    has

    ve

    busi

    ness

    days

    and

    am

    onth

    has

    twen

    ty-t

    wo.

    Sou

    rce:

    Au

    thor

    s’ow

    nca

    lcul

    atio

    ns.

    Cos

    tT

    he

    cost

    ofob

    tain

    ing

    lega

    lst

    atus

    toop

    erat

    ea

    rm

    asa

    shar

    eof

    per

    capi

    taG

    DP

    in19

    99.I

    tin

    clu

    des

    all

    iden

    tia

    ble

    ofc

    ial

    expe

    nses

    (fee

    s,co

    sts

    ofpr

    oced

    ures

    and

    form

    s,ph

    otoc

    opie

    s,s

    cal

    stam

    ps,l

    egal

    and

    nota

    rych

    arge

    s,et

    c.).

    The

    com

    pan

    yis

    assu

    med

    toh

    ave

    ast

    art-

    up

    capi

    tal

    ofte

    nti

    mes

    per

    capi

    taG

    DP

    in19

    99.S

    ourc

    e:A

    uth

    ors’

    own

    calc

    ulat

    ions

    .C

    ost

    1ti

    me

    Th

    eco

    stof

    obta

    inin

    gle

    gal

    stat

    usto

    oper

    ate

    ar

    mas

    ash

    are

    ofpe

    rca

    pita

    GD

    Pin

    1999

    .It

    incl

    ude

    sal

    lid

    enti

    abl

    eof

    cia

    lex

    pens

    es(f

    ees,

    cost

    sof

    proc

    edur

    esan

    dfo

    rms,

    phot

    ocop

    ies,

    sca

    lst

    amps

    ,leg

    alan

    dno

    tary

    char

    ges,

    etc.

    )as

    wel

    las

    the

    mon

    etiz

    edva

    lue

    ofth

    een

    trep

    rene

    ur’

    sti

    me.

    The

    tim

    eof

    the

    entr

    epre

    neu

    ris

    valu

    edas

    the

    prod

    uct

    ofti

    me

    and

    per

    capi

    taG

    DP

    in19

    99ex

    pres

    sed

    inpe

    rbu

    sine

    ssda

    yte

    rms.

    The

    com

    pan

    yis

    assu

    med

    toh

    ave

    ast

    art-

    upca

    pita

    lof

    ten

    tim

    esth

    eG

    DP

    per

    capi

    tale

    vel

    in19

    99.S

    ourc

    e:A

    uth

    ors’

    own

    calc

    ula

    tion

    s.G

    DP

    /PO

    P1

    999

    Gro

    ssdo

    mes

    tic

    prod

    uct

    per

    capi

    tain

    curr

    ent

    U.S

    .dol

    lars

    in19

    99.S

    ourc

    e:W

    orld

    Ban

    k[2

    001]

    .Q

    ual

    ity

    stan

    dard

    sN

    umbe

    rof

    ISO

    9000

    cert

    ica

    tion

    spe

    rth

    ousa

    ndin

    habi

    tan

    tsis

    sued

    byth

    eIn

    tern

    atio

    nal

    Org

    aniz

    atio

    nfo

    rS

    tand

    ardi

    zati

    onas

    of19

    99to

    each

    cou

    ntry

    inth

    esa

    mpl

    e.“I

    SO

    stan

    dard

    sre

    pres

    ent

    anin

    tern

    atio

    nal

    cons

    ensu

    son

    the

    stat

    eof

    the

    art

    inth

    ete

    chno

    logy

    conc

    erne

    d...

    .IS

    O90

    00is

    prim

    aril

    yco

    nce

    rned

    wit

    hqu

    alit

    ym

    anag

    emen

    t...

    .IS

    Ode

    velo

    psvo

    lunt

    ary

    tech

    nica

    lst

    anda

    rds

    that

    cont

    ribu

    teto

    mak

    ing

    the

    deve

    lopm

    ent,

    man

    ufac

    turi

    ngan

    dsu

    pply

    ofpr

    odu

    cts

    and

    serv

    ices

    mor

    eef

    cie

    nt,

    safe

    ran

    dcl

    eane

    r...

    .ISO

    stan

    dard

    sal

    sose

    rve

    tosa

    fegu

    ard

    cons

    umer

    s...

    .Whe

    nan

    orga

    niz

    atio

    nh

    asa

    man

    agem

    ent

    syst

    emce

    rti

    edto

    anIS

    O90

    00..

    .,th

    ism

    eans

    that

    the

    proc

    ess

    inu

    enci

    ng

    qual

    ity

    (IS

    O90

    00).

    ..co

    nfor

    ms

    toth

    ere

    leva

    ntst

    anda

    rd’s

    requ

    irem

    ents

    .”S

    ourc

    e:In

    tern

    atio

    nal

    Org

    aniz

    atio

    nfo

    rS

    tand

    ardi

    zati

    on(w

    ww

    .iso

    .ch

    ).W

    ater

    poll

    utio

    nE

    mis

    sion

    sof

    orga

    nic

    wat

    erpo

    llut

    ants

    (kil

    ogra

    ms

    per

    day

    per

    wor

    ker)

    for

    1998

    .Mea

    sure

    din

    term

    sof

    bioc

    hem

    ical

    oxyg

    ende

    man

    d,w

    hich

    refe

    rsto

    the

    amou

    ntof

    oxyg

    enth

    atba

    cter

    iain

    wat

    erw

    ill

    cons

    ume

    inbr

    eaki

    ng

    dow

    nw

    aste

    .Em

    issi

    ons

    per

    wor

    ker

    are

    tota

    lem

    issi

    ons

    divi

    ded

    byth

    en

    umbe

    rof

    indu

    stri

    alw

    orke

    rs.S

    ourc

    e:W

    orld

    Ban

    k[2

    001]

    .

    16 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

    http://www.iso.ch

  • Dea

    ths

    from

    acci

    dent

    alpo

    ison

    ing

    Log

    ofth

    enu

    mbe

    rof

    deat

    hs

    cau

    sed

    byac

    cide

    ntal

    pois

    onin

    gs(i

    nclu

    din

    gby

    drug

    s,m

    edic

    atio

    ns,b

    io-p

    rodu

    cts,

    soli

    dan

    dliq

    uid

    subs

    tanc

    es,

    gase

    san

    dva

    pors

    )pe

    rm

    illi

    onin

    habi

    tan

    ts.A

    vera

    geof

    the

    year

    s19

    81th

    roug

    h19

    94(t

    hem

    ost

    rece

    ntav

    aila

    ble

    gur

    e).

    Sour

    ce:T

    henu

    mbe

    rof

    acci

    dent

    alde

    aths

    from

    pois

    onin

    gis

    take

    nfr

    omW

    orld

    Hea

    lth

    Org

    aniz

    atio

    n[1

    998]

    .P

    opul

    atio

    ng

    ures

    are

    take

    nfr

    omW

    orld

    Ban

    k[2

    001]

    .D

    eath

    sfr

    omin

    test

    inal

    infe

    ctio

    ns

    Log

    ofth

    enu

    mbe

    rof

    deat

    hs

    cau

    sed

    byin

    test

    inal

    infe

    ctio

    ns(i

    nclu

    din

    gdi

    gest

    ive

    diso

    rder

    s)pe

    rm

    illio

    nin

    habi

    tan

    ts.A

    vera

    geof

    the

    year

    s19

    81th

    roug

    h19

    94(t

    hem

    ost

    rece

    ntav

    aila

    ble

    gu

    re).

    Sour

    ce:T

    henu

    mbe

    rof

    deat

    hsfr

    omin

    test

    inal

    infe

    ctio

    nsis

    take

    nfr

    omW

    orld

    Hea

    lth

    Org

    aniz

    atio

    n[1

    998]

    .P

    opul

    atio

    n

    gure

    sar

    eta

    ken

    from

    Wor

    ldB

    ank

    [200

    1].

    Siz

    eof

    the

    uno

    fci

    alec

    onom

    yS

    ize

    ofth

    esh

    adow

    econ

    omy

    asa

    perc

    enta

    geof

    GD

    P(v

    aryi

    ngti

    me

    peri

    ods)

    .Sou

    rce:

    Aut

    hor

    s’ow

    nco

    mpu

    tati

    ons

    base

    don

    aver

    agin

    gov

    eral

    les

    tim

    ates

    repo

    rted

    inS

    chne

    ider

    and

    Ens

    te[2

    000]

    for

    any

    give

    nco

    unt

    ryas

    wel

    las

    San

    anik

    one

    [199

    6]fo

    rB

    urki

    naF

    aso,

    Ch

    idze

    ro[1

    996]

    for

    Sen

    egal

    ,Tu

    rnha

    man

    dS

    chw

    artz

    [199

    0]fo

    rIn

    don

    esia

    and

    Pak

    ista

    n,a

    ndK

    asna

    kogl

    uan

    dY

    ayla

    [200

    0]fo

    rT

    urk

    ey.

    Em

    ploy

    men

    tin

    the

    uno

    fci

    alec

    onom

    yS

    hare

    ofth

    ela

    bor

    forc

    eem

    ploy

    edin

    the

    unof

    cia

    lec

    onom

    yin

    the

    capi

    tal

    city

    ofea

    chco

    untr

    yas

    ape

    rcen

    tof

    the

    ofc

    ial

    labo

    r.F

    igur

    esar

    eba

    sed

    onsu

    rvey

    san

    d,fo

    rso

    me

    coun

    trie

    s,on

    econ

    omet

    ric

    esti

    mat

    es.S

    ourc

    e:S

    chne

    ider

    [200

    0]an

    dth

    eG

    loba

    lU

    rban

    Indi

    cato

    rsD

    atab

    ase

    [200

    0](w

    ww

    .urb

    anob

    serv

    ator

    y.or

    g/in

    dic

    ator

    s/da

    taba

    se).

    Pro

    duct

    mar

    ket

    com

    peti

    tion

    Sur

    vey

    mea

    sure

    ofth

    eex

    ten

    tto

    whi

    chre

    spon

    dent

    sag

    ree

    wit

    hth

    efo

    llow

    ing

    stat

    emen

    t:“C

    ompe

    titi

    onin

    the

    loca

    lm

    arke

    tis

    inte

    nse

    and

    mar

    ket

    shar

    esu

    ctua

    teco

    nsta

    ntl

    y.”

    Scal

    efr

    om1

    (str

    ongl

    ydi

    sagr

    ee)

    thro

    ugh

    7(s

    tron

    gly

    agre

    e).S

    ourc

    e:IM

    D[2

    001]

    .C

    orru

    ptio

    nC

    orru

    ptio

    npe

    rcep

    tion

    inde

    xfo

    r19

    99.

    Cor

    rupt

    ion

    isde

    ne

    dbr

    oadl

    yas

    “the

    mis

    use

    ofpu

    blic

    pow

    erfo

    rpr

    ivat

    ebe

    net

    s,e.

    g.,

    brib

    ing

    ofpu

    blic

    ofc

    ials

    ,ki

    ckba

    cks

    inpu

    blic

    proc

    urem

    ent,

    orem

    bezz

    lem

    ent

    ofpu

    blic

    fun

    ds.”

    Th

    ein

    dex

    aver

    ages

    the

    corr

    upt

    ion

    scor

    esgi

    ven

    byth

    efo

    llow

    ing

    sour

    ces:

    (1)

    Fre

    edom

    Hou

    seN

    atio

    nsin

    Tra

    nsit

    (FH

    );(2

    )G

    allu

    pIn

    tern

    atio

    nal

    (GI)

    ;(3)

    the

    Eco

    nom

    ist

    Inte

    llige

    nce

    Uni

    t(E

    IU);

    (4)

    the

    Inst

    itu

    tefo

    rM

    anag

    emen

    tD

    evel

    opm

    ent,

    Lau

    sann

    e(I

    MD

    );(5

    )th

    eIn

    tern

    atio

    nal

    Cri

    me

    Vic

    tim

    Sur

    vey

    (IC

    VS

    );(6

    )th

    eP

    olit

    ical

    and

    Eco

    nom

    icR

    isk

    Con

    sult

    ancy

    ,H

    ong

    Kon

    g(P

    ER

    C);

    (7)

    Th

    eW

    all

    Str

    eet

    Jour

    nal

    ,C

    entr

    alE

    urop

    ean

    Eco

    nom

    icR

    evie

    w(C

    EE

    R);

    (8)

    the

    Wor

    ldB

    ank

    and

    Uni

    vers

    ity

    ofB

    asel

    (WB

    /UB

    ),(9

    )th

    eW

    orld

    Eco

    nom

    icF

    oru

    m(W

    EF

    ).D

    esce

    ndi

    ngsc

    ore

    from

    1(m

    ost

    corr

    upt

    )to

    10(l

    east

    corr

    upt)

    .Sou

    rce:

    Tra

    nspa

    ren

    cyIn

    tern

    atio

    nal

    (ww

    w.t

    ran

    spar

    ency

    .de/

    ).E

    xecu

    tive

    defa

    cto

    inde

    pend

    ence

    Inde

    xof

    “ope

    rati

    on(d

    efa

    cto)

    inde

    pend

    ence

    ofch

    ief

    exec

    utiv

    e.”

    Des

    cend

    ing

    scal

    efr

    om1

    to7

    (15

    pure

    indi

    vidu

    al;2

    5in

    term

    edia

    teca

    tego

    ry;3

    5sl

    ight

    tom

    oder

    ate

    lim

    itat

    ions

    ;45

    inte

    rmed

    iate

    cate

    gory

    ;55

    subs

    tan

    tial

    lim

    itat

    ions

    ;65

    inte

    rmed

    iate

    cate

    gory

    ;75

    exec

    utiv

    epa

    rity

    orsu

    bord

    inat

    ion)

    .A

    vera

    geof

    the

    year

    s19

    45th

    roug

    h19

    98.S

    ourc

    e:J

    agge

    rsan

    dM

    arsh

    all

    [200

    0].

    Con

    stra

    ints

    onex

    ecut

    ive

    pow

    erIn

    dex

    ofco

    nstr

    ain

    tson

    the

    exec

    utiv

    epo

    wer

    base

    don

    the

    num

    ber

    ofef

    fect

    ive

    veto

    poin

    tsin

    aco

    unt

    ry.V

    eto

    poin

    tsin

    clud

    e(1

    )an

    effe

    ctiv

    ele

    gisl

    atu

    re(r

    epre

    sent

    stw

    ove

    topo

    ints

    inth

    eca

    seof

    bica

    mer

    alsy

    stem

    s);(

    2)an

    inde

    pend

    ent

    judi

    ciar

    y;an

    d(3

    )a

    stro

    ngfe

    dera

    lsy

    stem

    .Ave

    rage

    ofth

    eye

    ars

    1945

    thro

    ugh

    1998

    .Sou

    rce:

    Hen

    isz

    [200

    1].

    Eff

    ecti

    vene

    ssof

    legi

    slat

    ure

    Inde

    xof

    the

    effe

    ctiv

    enes

    sof

    the

    legi

    slat

    ure

    .A

    scen

    din

    gsc

    ale

    from

    1to

    4(1

    5no

    legi

    slat

    ure;

    25

    larg

    ely

    inef

    fect

    ive;

    35

    part

    lyef

    fect

    ive;

    45

    effe

    ctiv

    e).

    Ave

    rage

    ofth

    eye

    ars

    1945

    thro

    ugh

    1998

    .Sou

    rce:

    Th

    eC

    ross

    -Nat

    iona

    lT

    ime-

    Ser

    ies

    Dat

    aA

    rchi

    ve(w

    ww

    .dat

    aban

    ks.s

    iteh

    osti

    ng.n

    et/w

    ww

    /m

    ain

    .htm

    ).C

    ompe

    titi

    onin

    the

    legi

    slat

    ure’

    sno

    min

    atin

    gpr

    oces

    s

    Inde

    xof

    the

    com

    peti

    tive

    ness

    ofth

    eno

    min

    atin

    gpr

    oces

    sfo

    rse

    ats

    inth

    ele

    gisl

    atur

    e.A

    scen

    ding

    scal

    efr

    om1

    to4

    (15

    nole

    gisl

    atur

    e;2

    5n

    onco

    mpe

    titi

    ve;

    35

    part

    lyco

    mpe

    titi

    ve;4

    5co

    mpe

    titi

    ve).

    Ave

    rage

    ofth

    eye

    ars

    1945

    thro

    ugh

    1998

    .So

    urce

    :Th

    eC

    ross

    -Nat

    iona

    lT

    ime-

    Ser

    ies

    Dat

    aA

    rchi

    ve(w

    ww

    .dat

    aban

    ks.s

    iteh

    osti

    ng.

    net/

    ww

    w/m

    ain.

    htm

    ).A

    utoc

    racy

    Indi

    cate

    sth

    e“g

    ener

    alcl

    osed

    nes

    sof

    polit

    ical

    inst

    itut

    ion

    s.”

    Sca

    lefr

    om0

    to10

    wit

    h0

    bein

    glo

    win

    auto

    crac

    yan

    d10

    bein

    ghi

    ghin

    auto

    crac

    y.A

    vera

    geof

    the

    year

    s19

    45th

    rou

    gh19

    98.

    Sour

    ce:J

    agge

    rsan

    dM

    arsh

    all

    [200

    0].

    Pol

    itic

    alri

    ghts

    Inde

    xof

    polit

    ical

    righ

    ts.H

    ighe

    rra

    ting

    sin

    dica

    teco

    untr

    ies

    that

    com

    ecl

    oser

    toth

    eid

    eals

    sugg

    este

    dby

    the

    chec

    klis

    tqu

    esti

    ons

    of(1

    )fr

    eean

    dfa

    irel

    ecti

    ons;

    (2)

    thos

    eel

    ecte

    dru

    le;(

    3)th

    ere

    are

    com

    peti

    tive

    part

    ies

    orot

    her

    com

    peti

    tive

    polit

    ical

    grou

    ping

    s;(4

    )th

    eop

    posi

    tion

    has

    anim

    port

    ant

    role

    and

    pow

    er;a

    nd(5

    )th

    een

    titi

    esha

    vese

    lf-de

    term

    inat

    ion

    oran

    extr

    emel

    yhi

    ghde

    gree

    ofau

    tono

    my.

    Ave

    rage

    ofth

    eye

    ars

    1972

    thro

    ugh

    1998

    .Sou

    rce:

    Fre

    edom

    Hou

    se[2

    001]

    .L

    egal

    orig

    inId

    enti

    es

    the

    lega

    lor

    igin

    ofea

    chC

    ompa

    nyL

    awor

    Com

    mer

    cial

    Cod

    eof

    each

    coun

    try.

    Th

    ere

    are

    ve

    poss

    ible

    orig

    ins:

    (1)

    Eng

    lish

    Com

    mon

    Law

    ;(2

    )F

    ren

    chC

    omm

    erci

    alC

    ode;

    (3)

    Ger

    man

    Com

    mer

    cial

    Cod

    e;(4

    )Sc

    andi

    navi

    anC

    omm

    erci

    alC

    ode;

    and

    (5)

    Soc

    iali

    st/C

    omm

    unis

    tla

    ws.

    Sou

    rce:

    La

    Por

    taet

    al.

    [199

    8];

    Rey

    nold

    san

    dF

    lore

    s[1

    989]

    ;CIA

    Wor

    ldF

    actb

    ook

    [200

    1].

    17THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

    http://www.urbanobservatory.org/indicators/database%29.http://www.transparency.de/%29.http://www.databanks.sitehosting.net/www/main.htm%29.http://www.databanks.sitehosting.net/www/main.htm%29.

  • TA

    BL

    EII

    IT

    HE

    DA

    TA

    Pan

    elA

    repo

    rts

    the

    tota

    lnu

    mbe

    rof

    proc

    edu

    res

    and

    thei

    rbr

    eaku

    pin

    the

    foll

    owin

    gv

    eca

    tego

    ries

    :(1

    )sa

    fety

    and

    heal

    th;

    (2)

    envi

    ronm

    ent;

    (3)

    taxe

    s;(4

    )la

    bor;

    and

    (5)

    scre

    enin

    g.T

    he

    tabl

    eal

    sore

    port

    sth

    eti

    me,

    dire

    ctco

    st(a

    sa

    frac

    tion

    ofG

    DP

    per

    capi

    tain

    1999

    )as

    soci

    ated

    wit

    hm

    eeti

    nggo

    vern

    men

    tre

    quir

    emen

    ts,

    and

    dire

    ctco

    stpl

    us

    the

    mon

    etiz

    edva

    lue

    ofth

    een

    trep

    rene

    ur’s

    tim

    e(a

    sa

    frac

    tion

    ofG

    DP

    per

    capi

    tain

    1999

    )as

    wel

    las

    the

    leve

    lof

    GD

    Ppe

    rca

    pita

    indo

    llar

    sin

    1999

    .Cou

    ntr

    ies

    are

    sort

    edin

    asce

    ndin

    gor

    der

    onth

    eba

    sis

    of(1

    )th

    eto

    tal

    num

    ber

    ofpr

    oced

    ures

    ;(2

    )ti

    me;

    and

    (3)

    cost

    .P

    anel

    Bpr

    esen

    tsm

    eans

    ofth

    eva

    riab

    les

    byqu

    arti

    les

    ofG

    DP

    per

    capi

    tain

    1999

    .P

    anel

    Cpr

    esen

    tst-

    stat

    isti

    csfo

    rdi

    ffer

    ence

    sin

    mea

    ns

    acro

    ssqu

    arti

    les

    ofpe

    rca

    pita

    GD

    Pin

    1999

    .T

    able

    IIde

    scri

    bes

    the

    vari

    able

    sin

    deta

    il.

    Num

    ber

    ofpr

    oced

    ures

    Saf

    ety

    &H

    ealt

    hE

    nvir

    onm

    ent

    Tax

    esL

    abor

    Scre

    enin

    gT

    ime

    Cos

    tC

    ost

    1ti

    me

    GD

    P/

    PO

    P1

    999

    Pan

    elA

    :D

    ata

    Can

    ada

    20

    01

    01

    20.

    0145

    0.02

    2519

    ,320

    Aus

    tral

    ia2

    00

    10

    12

    0.02

    250.

    0305

    20,0

    50N

    ewZe

    alan

    d3

    00

    10

    23

    0.00

    530.

    0173

    13,7

    80D

    enm

    ark

    30

    01

    02

    30.

    1000

    0.11

    2032

    ,030

    Irel

    and

    30

    01

    02

    160.

    1157

    0.17

    9719

    ,160

    Un

    ited

    Sta

    tes

    40

    01

    12

    40.

    0049

    0.01

    6930

    ,600

    Nor

    way

    40

    01

    12

    180.

    0472

    0.11

    9232

    ,880

    Un

    ited

    Kin

    gdom

    50

    01

    13

    40.

    0143

    0.03

    0322

    ,640

    Hon

    gK

    ong

    50

    00

    14

    150.

    0333

    0.09

    3323

    ,520

    Mon

    goli

    a5

    00

    10

    422

    0.03

    310.

    1211

    350

    Fin

    land

    50

    01

    31

    240.

    0116

    0.10

    7623

    ,780

    Isra

    el5

    00

    21

    232

    0.21

    320.

    3412

    15,8

    60Zi

    mba

    bwe

    50

    02

    12

    470.

    1289

    0.31

    6952

    0S

    wed

    en6

    00

    11

    413

    0.02

    560.

    0776

    25,0

    40Ja

    mai

    ca6

    00

    21

    324

    0.18

    790.

    2839

    2,33

    0Za

    mbi

    a6

    00

    21

    329

    0.60

    490.

    7209

    320

    Pan

    ama

    70

    01

    15

    150.

    3074

    0.36

    743,

    070

    Sw

    itze

    rlan

    d7

    00

    21

    416

    0.17

    240.

    2364

    38,3

    50S

    inga

    pore

    70

    01

    24

    220.

    1191

    0.20

    7129

    ,610

    Lat

    via

    70

    02

    14

    230.

    4234

    0.51

    542,

    470

    Mal

    aysi

    a7

    00

    11

    542

    0.26

    450.

    4325

    3,40

    0

    18 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • Sri

    Lan

    ka8

    00

    11

    623

    0.19

    720.

    2892

    820

    Net

    herl

    ands

    80

    12

    05

    310.

    1841

    0.30

    8124

    ,320

    Bel

    gium

    80

    01

    25

    330.

    0998

    0.23

    1824

    ,510

    Tai

    wan

    ,Ch

    ina

    80

    01

    25

    370.

    0660

    0.21

    4013

    ,248

    Hun

    gary

    80

    01

    16

    390.

    8587

    1.01

    474,

    650

    Pak

    ista

    n8

    00

    21

    550

    0.34

    960.

    5496

    470

    Per

    u8

    00

    22

    483

    0.19

    860.

    5306

    2,39

    0S

    outh

    Afr

    ica

    90

    02

    25

    260.

    0844

    0.18

    843,

    160

    Kyr

    gyz

    Rep

    ubli

    c9

    00

    11

    732

    0.25

    320.

    3812

    300

    Tha

    ilan

    d9

    00

    32

    435

    0.06

    390.

    2039

    1,96

    0N

    iger

    ia9

    01

    21

    536

    2.57

    002.

    7140

    310

    Aus

    tria

    90

    02

    16

    370.

    2728

    0.42

    0825

    ,970

    Tun

    isia

    90

    00

    27

    410.

    1722

    0.33

    622,

    100

    Slo

    veni

    a9

    00

    01

    847

    0.21

    030.

    3983

    9,89

    0L

    eban

    on9

    00

    11

    763

    1.56

    721.

    8192

    3,70

    0U

    rugu

    ay10

    00

    14

    523

    0.49

    490.

    5869

    5,90

    0B

    ulga

    ria

    100

    02

    08

    270.

    1441

    0.25

    211,

    380

    Chi

    le10

    00

    32

    528

    0.13

    080.

    2428

    4,74

    0G

    erm

    any

    100

    01

    27

    420.

    1569

    0.32

    4925

    ,350

    Gh

    ana

    100

    11

    44

    450.

    2175

    0.39

    7539

    0L

    ith

    uani

    a10

    20

    21

    546

    0.05

    460.

    2386

    2,62

    0C

    zech

    Rep

    ubli

    c10

    00

    12

    765

    0.08

    220.

    3422

    5,06

    0In

    dia

    100

    03

    34

    770.

    5776

    0.88

    5645

    0Ja

    pan

    110

    02

    27

    260.

    1161

    0.22

    0132

    ,230

    Uga

    nda

    112

    02

    16

    290.

    3040

    0.42

    0032

    0E

    gypt

    ,Ara

    bR

    ep.

    110

    02

    18

    510.

    9659

    1.16

    991,

    400

    Ken

    ya11

    00

    23

    654

    0.50

    700.

    7230

    360

    Arm

    enia

    110

    01

    19

    550.

    1267

    0.34

    6749

    0P

    olan

    d11

    20

    31

    558

    0.25

    460.

    4866

    3,96

    0S

    pain

    110

    04

    25

    820.

    1730

    0.50

    1014

    ,000

    Indo

    nes

    ia11

    00

    21

    812

    80.

    5379

    1.04

    9958

    0C

    roat

    ia12

    10

    23

    638

    0.45

    030.

    6023

    4,58

    0K

    azak

    hsta

    n12

    00

    13

    842

    0.47

    470.

    6427

    1,23

    0P

    ortu

    gal

    120

    02

    28

    760.

    1844

    0.48

    8410

    ,600

    Slo

    vak

    Rep

    ubl

    ic12

    00

    23

    789

    0.14

    520.

    5012

    3,59

    0C

    hina

    120

    05

    25

    920.

    1417

    0.50

    9778

    0

    19THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • TA

    BL

    EII

    I(C

    ON

    TIN

    UE

    D)

    Num

    ber

    ofpr

    oced

    ures

    Saf

    ety

    &H

    ealt

    hE

    nvi

    ronm

    ent

    Tax

    esL

    abor

    Scr

    eeni

    ngT

    ime

    Cos

    tC

    ost

    1ti

    me

    GD

    P/

    PO

    P19

    99

    Kor

    ea,

    Rep

    .13

    00

    24

    727

    0.16

    270.

    2707

    8,49

    0T

    anza

    nia

    131

    05

    25

    293.

    3520

    3.46

    8024

    0U

    krai

    ne13

    00

    23

    830

    0.25

    690.

    3769

    750

    Tur

    key

    130

    02

    29

    440.

    1932

    0.36

    922,

    900

    Mal

    awi

    135

    21

    14

    520.

    1886

    0.39

    6619

    0M

    oroc

    co13

    10

    33

    657

    0.21

    260.

    4406

    1,20

    0G

    eorg

    ia13

    20

    11

    969

    0.60

    480.

    8808

    620

    Bur

    kina

    Fas

    o14

    00

    32

    933

    3.18

    833.

    3203

    240

    Phi

    lipp

    ines

    140

    05

    18

    460.

    1897

    0.37

    371,

    020

    Arg

    enti

    na14

    00

    45

    548

    0.10

    190.

    2939

    7,60

    0Jo

    rdan

    141

    02

    110

    640.

    5369

    0.79

    291,

    500

    Ven

    ezu

    ela

    141

    13

    36

    104

    0.10

    600.

    5220

    3,67

    0G

    reec

    e15

    00

    42

    936

    0.58

    600.

    7300

    11,7

    70F

    ranc

    e15

    00

    31

    1153

    0.14

    300.

    3550

    23,4

    80B

    razi

    l15

    00

    75

    363

    0.20

    140.

    4534

    4,42

    0M

    exic

    o15

    12

    23

    767

    0.56

    640.

    8344

    4,40

    0M

    ali

    161

    03

    210

    5924

    0It

    aly

    160

    05

    38

    620.

    2002

    0.44

    8219

    ,710

    Sen

    egal

    160

    03

    211

    691.

    2331

    1.50

    9151

    0E

    cuad

    or16

    20

    24

    872

    0.62

    230.

    9103

    1,31

    0R

    oman

    ia16

    12

    13

    997

    0.15

    310.

    5411

    1,52

    0V

    ietn

    am16

    01

    15

    911

    21.

    3377

    1.78

    5737

    0M

    adag

    asca

    r17

    00

    73

    715

    20.

    4263

    1.03

    4325

    0C

    olom

    bia

    182

    04

    57

    480.

    1480

    0.34

    002,

    250

    Moz

    ambi

    que

    194

    01

    311

    149

    1.11

    461.

    7106

    230

    Rus

    sian

    Fed

    erat

    ion

    200

    02

    513

    570.

    1979

    0.42

    592,

    270

    Bol

    ivia

    200

    12

    710

    882.

    6558

    3.00

    781,

    010

    Dom

    inic

    anR

    epub

    lic

    210

    02

    316

    804.

    6309

    4.95

    0919

    1S

    amp

    leav

    erag

    e10

    .48

    0.34

    0.14

    2.04

    1.94

    6.04

    47.4

    00.

    4708

    0.65

    988,

    226

    20 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • Pan

    elB

    :M

    eans

    byQ

    uar

    tile

    sof

    GD

    Ppe

    rca

    pita

    in19

    99

    1st

    Qua

    rtile

    6.77

    0.00

    0.05

    1.59

    1.14

    4.00

    24.5

    00.

    100.

    2024

    ,372

    2nd

    Qua

    rtil

    e11

    .10

    0.24

    0.14

    2.14

    2.38

    6.19

    49.2

    90.

    330.

    535,

    847

    3rd

    Qua

    rtil

    e12

    .33

    0.52

    0.14

    2.19

    2.33

    7.14

    53.1

    00.

    410.

    621,

    568

    4th

    Qu

    arti

    le11

    .90

    0.62

    0.24

    2.24

    1.95

    6.90

    63.7

    61.

    081.

    3434

    9

    Pan

    elC

    :Tes

    tof

    mea

    ns

    (t-s

    tati

    stic

    s)

    1st

    vs.2

    nd

    Qu

    arti

    le2

    4.20

    a2

    2.07

    b2

    0.87

    21.

    352

    3.64

    a2

    3.34

    a2

    3.71

    a2

    3.03

    a2

    3.97

    a12

    .03a

    1st

    vs.3

    rdQ

    uar

    tile

    24.

    58a

    23.

    02a

    20.

    872

    1.64

    b2

    2.82

    a2

    4.07

    a2

    4.21

    a2

    2.54

    b2

    3.19

    a16

    .35a

    1st

    vs.4

    thQ

    uart

    ile

    24.

    04a

    22.

    08a

    21.

    552

    1.61

    22.

    43b

    23.

    18a

    24.

    09a

    23.

    53a

    24.

    06a

    17.3

    1a

    2nd

    vs.

    3rd

    Qu

    arti

    le2

    1.17

    21.

    340.

    002

    0.11

    0.10

    21.

    512

    0.54

    20.

    522

    0.59

    6.14

    a

    2nd

    vs.

    4th

    Qua

    rtil

    e2

    0.72

    21.

    172

    0.61

    20.

    211.

    102

    0.89

    21.

    462

    2.54

    b2

    2.73

    a8.

    05a

    3rd

    vs.

    4th

    Qua

    rtil

    e0.

    332

    0.27

    20.

    612

    0.11

    0.82

    0.26

    21.

    062

    2.17

    b2

    2.27

    b8.

    53a

    a.S

    igni

    can

    tat

    1pe

    rcen

    t;b.

    sign

    ica

    ntat

    5pe

    rcen

    t;c.

    sign

    ica

    nt

    at10

    perc

    ent.

    21THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • reported in Panel C). Rich countries also have fewer safety andhealth, tax, and labor start-up procedures than the rest of thesample. Similarly, meeting government requirements takes ap-proximately 24.5 business days in rich countries, statisticallysignicantly lower than the rest-of-sample mean of 55.4 days. Incontrast, countries in the other three quartiles of per capitaincome are not statistically different from each other in the num-ber of procedures and the time it takes to complete them.

    To summarize, the regulation of entry varies enormouslyacross countries. It often takes the form of screening procedures.Rich countries (i.e., those in the top quartile of per capita GDP)regulate entry relatively less than do all the other countries. Inprinciple, these ndings are consistent with both the public choiceand public interest theories. Market failures might be more per-vasive in countries with incomes just below the rst quartile ofGDP per capita, generating a greater demand for benign regula-tion in these countries. Alternatively, income levels may proxy forcharacteristics of political systems that allow politicians or in-cumbent rms to capture the regulatory process for their ownbenet. In the next two sections we relate these patterns in thedata to the theories of regulation.

    IV. WHO GETS THE RENTS FROM REGULATION?

    Theories of regulation differ in their predictions as to whogets its benets. The public interest theory predicts that stricterentry regulation is associated with higher measured consumerwelfare. In contrast, the public choice theory sees regulation as atool to create rents for bureaucrats or incumbent rms. Stricterregulation should then be associated with higher corruption andless competition.

    Measuring rents is inherently extremely difcult, especiallyacross countries. In this section, we present some measures thatwe have been able to nd that bear—albeit quite imperfectly—onthe relevant theories. To begin, consider some variables bearingon the public interest theory. These variables reect the activitiesof all rms in the country, and not just the entrants. The rst isa measure of a country’s compliance with international qualitystandards. It is a natural variable to focus on if the goal ofregulation is to screen out entrants who might sell output ofinferior quality. Second, we consider the level of water pollution,which should fall if entry regulation aims to control externalities

    22 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • and does so successfully.8 Third, we consider two measures ofhealth outcomes that publicly interested entry regulation wouldguard against: the number of deaths from accidental poisoningand from intestinal infections.9 In addition, we include two mea-sures of the size of the unofcial economy based on estimates ofunofcial output and employment, respectively. Since rms op-erating unofcially avoid nearly all regulations, a large size of theunofcial economy in countries with more regulations under-mines the prediction of the public interest theory that regulationeffectively protects consumers.10 Finally, we use a survey mea-sure of “product market competition.” Stiffer entry regulationshould be associated with greater competition in the public inter-est theory, and lacking competition in the public choice theory,especially in its regulatory capture version.

    Table IV presents the results on these seven measures ofconsequences of regulation using the number of procedures asdependent variables. For two reasons, we run each regressionwith and without the log of per capita GDP. First, the number ofprocedures is correlated with income per capita, and we want tomake sure that we are not picking up the general effects of goodgovernance associated with higher income. Second, we use GDPper capita as a rough proxy of the prevalence of market failures ina country. Including per capita income as a control is a crude wayto keep the need for socially desirable regulation constant, whichallows us to focus on the consequences (and later causes) ofregulation separately from the need.

    The results in Table IV show that compliance with interna-tional quality standards declines as the number of proceduresrises. Pollution levels do not fall with regulation levels. The twomeasures of accidental poisoning are not lower in countries withmore regulations (if anything, the opposite seems to be true evencontrolling for per capita income). More regulation is associatedwith a larger unofcial economy, and statistically signicantly soif we use the unofcial employment variable. Competition incountries with more regulation is perceived to be less intense,

    8. We have tried measures of air pollution and obtained similar results.9. Due to reporting practices in poor countries, the second variable might

    better capture deaths from accidental poisoning in the poor countries, according tothe World Health Organization [1998].

    10. There is a large literature detailing how regulation can drive rms intothe unofcial economy, where they can avoid some or all of these regulations. See,for example, Johnson, Kaufmann, and Shleifer [1997] and Friedman, Johnson,Kaufmann, and Zoido-Lobaton [2000].

    23THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • TABLE IVEVIDENCE ON REGULATION AND SOCIAL OUTCOMES

    The table presents the results of OLS regressions using the followingseven dependent variables: (1) Quality standards as proxied by the numberof ISO 9000 certications; (2) Water pollution; (3) Deaths from accidentalpoisoning; (4) Deaths from intestinal infection; (5) Size of the unofcialeconomy as a fraction of GDP; (6) Employment in the unofcial economy;and (7) Product market competition. The independent variables are the logof the number of procedures and the log of per capita GDP in dollars in1999. Table II describes all variables in detail. Robust standard errors areshown below the coefcients.

    Dependent variableNumber ofprocedures

    LnGDP/POP1999 Constant

    R2

    N

    Quality standards (ISOCertications)

    2 0.2781a 0.7649a 0.3311(0.0496) (0.1268) 85

    2 0.1595a 0.0771a 2 0.1140 0.5384(0.0443) (0.0131) (0.1484) 85

    Water pollution 0.0127b 0.1557a 0.0247(0.0084) (0.0174) 76

    2 0.0037 2 0.0131a 0.2984a 0.2310(0.0076) (0.0027) (0.0314) 76

    Deaths from accidentalpoisoning 0.6588a 1.6357a 0.1179

    (0.2057) (0.4381) 570.0637 2 0.4525a 6.8347a 0.4109

    (0.1958) (0.0933) (1.0929) 57

    Deaths from intestinal infection 2.3049a 2 2.2697a 0.3451(0.3081) (0.6778) 611.0501a 2 0.8717a 7.8494a 0.6259

    (0.2971) (0.1012) (1.3048) 61

    Size of the unofcial economyd 14.7553a 2 3.7982 0.2482(2.5698) (5.2139) 736.4849b 2 6.1908a 67.1030a 0.5187

    (2.5385) (1.0834) (13.7059) 73

    Employment in the unofcialeconomy

    19.4438a 2 4.1103 0.3132(2.5756) (5.9160) 4613.8512a 2 4.4585a 41.5133b 0.4477

    2 3.6056 (1.3918) (17.6836) 46

    Product market competition 2 0.4012a 5.7571a 0.1405(0.1213) (0.2511) 54

    2 0.1418 0.2108a 3.3579a 0.3087(0.1202) (0.0680) (0.7749) 54

    a. Signicant at 1 percent; b. signicant at 5 percent; c. signicant at 10 percent.d. The regression on the size of the unofcial economy controls for the log of GDP per capita plus

    unofcial economy income (i.e., GDP per capita* (1 1 unofcial economy)) and not just by GDP per capita asall other regressions on the table do.

    24 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • although this result is only statistically signicant without theincome control. We have also run all regressions using cost andtime as independent variables, and obtained qualitatively similarresults. While the data are noisy, none of the results support thepredictions of the public interest theory.11

    The negative results in Table IV should be interpreted withcaution. First, some of our measures of public goods, such asdeaths from accidental poisoning, are probably more relevant forpoor countries, and in particular are unlikely to be inuenced byentry regulation for rich countries. Accordingly, it might be moreappropriate to perform the analysis separately for countries atdifferent income levels. To this end, we divide the sample at themedian per capita income and rerun the regressions in Table IVfor each subsample. The data do not support the proposition that,in the subsample of poorer countries, heavier regulation of entryis associated with better social outcomes or more competition.

    Second, an even deeper concern with the results in Table IVis that, despite our control for per capita income, there is impor-tant unobserved heterogeneity among countries correlated withregulation, which accounts for the results. For example, supposethat some countries have particularly egregious market failures,but also especially poor alternative mechanisms for dealing withthem, such as the press and the courts. Regulation, for example,might be less infected by corruption than either the press or thejudiciary. A publicly interested regulator in such countries wouldchoose to use more regulatory procedures because the alternativemethods of dealing with market failure are even worse, but stillend up with inferior outcomes.

    We cannot dismiss this concern with the results of Table IV,although our later ndings cast doubt on its validity. We run theregressions in Table IV using information on the freedom of thepress from Djankov, McLiesh, Nenova, and Shleifer [2001], andnd that, holding constant various measures of freedom of thepress and per capita income, the number of procedures is still notassociated with superior social outcomes. We also run the regres-sions in Table IV using a number of measures of citizen access to

    11. Using data for publicly traded rms, we have found no evidence thatcountries with heavier entry regulation have more protable rms, as measuredby the return on assets. These protability numbers, however, are very crude. Wealso measured protability using the return on World-Bank-nanced projectsfrom the World Bank Operations Evaluation Department. These data also yieldno evidence that more regulations are associated with greater returns.

    25THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • justice and of efciency of the judiciary from Djankov et al.[2001b]. Again, we nd that, holding constant these measuresand per capita income, the number of procedures is associated, ifanything, with inferior social outcomes.

    A direct implication of the tollbooth hypothesis is that cor-ruption levels and the intensity of entry regulation are positivelycorrelated. In fact, since in many countries in our sample politi-cians run businesses, the regulation of entry produces the doublebenet of corruption revenues and reduced competition for theincumbent businesses already afliated with the politicians. Fig-ure III presents the relationship between corruption and thenumber of procedures without controlling for per capita GDP.12

    Panel A of Table V shows statistically that, consistent with thetollbooth theory, more regulation is associated with worse corrup-tion scores. The coefcients are statistically signicant (with andwithout controlling for income) and large in economic terms. Theestimated coefcients imply that, controlling for per capita GDP,reducing the number of procedures by ten is associated with a

    12. We have tried a number of measures of corruption, all yielding similarresults. We have made sure that our results do not depend on “red tape” being partof the measure of corruption.

    FIGURE IIICorruption and Number of Procedures

    The scatter plot shows the values of the corruption index against the (log)number of procedures for the 78 countries in our sample with nonmissing data oncorruption.

    26 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

  • reduction in corruption of .8 of a standard deviation, roughly thedifference between France and Italy. The results using the costand the time of meeting the entry regulations as independent

    TABLE VEVIDENCE ON THE TOLLBOOTH THEORY

    The table presents the results of OLS regressions using corruption as thedependent variable. The independent variables are (1) the log of the numberof procedures; (2) the log of time; (3) the log of cost; and the log of per capitaGDP in dollars in 1999. Panel A presents results for the 78 observationswith available corruption data. Panel B reports results separately for thesubsample of countries with GDP per capita in 1999 above and below thesample median. Table II describes all variables in detail. Robust standarderrors are shown in parentheses below the coefcients.

    Panel A: Results for the whole sample

    Independentvariable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    Number ofprocedures

    2 3.1811a 2 1.8654a

    (0.2986) (0.2131)Time 2 1.7566a 2 0.8854a

    (0.1488) (0.1377)Cost 2 1.2129a 2 0.4978a

    (0.1206) (0.1285)Ln GDP/POP1999 0.9966

    a 0.9765a 0.9960a

    (0.0864) (0.1014) (0.1118)Constant 11.8741a 1.1345 11.0694a 0.0677 2.7520a 2 4.0893a

    (0.7380) (0.9299) (0.5932) (1.1176) (0.2414) (0.7867)R2 0.4656 0.8125 0.4387 0.7662 0.4256 0.7306N 78 78 78 78 78 78

    Panel B: Results for countries above and below the world median GDP per capita

    Countries abovemedian GDP/POP1999

    Countries belowmedian GDP/POP1999

    Independentvariable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    Number ofprocedures

    2 1.8729a 2 0.7841b

    (0.2971) (0.3304)Time 2 0.8135a 2 0.0923

    (0.1762) (0.2850)Cost 2 0.5327a 2 0.3408a

    (0.1894) (0.1021)Ln GDP/POP1999 1.4811

    a 1.5871a 1.7621a 0.3993b 0.3680c 0.2117(0.2265) (0.2789) (0.2913) (0.1735) (0.1802) (0.1718)

    Constant 2 3.6970 2 5.9027c 2 11.3736a 2.3246c 1.0098 1.3125(2.4628) (2.9942) (2.5773) (1.2849) (1.8813) (1.1136)

    R2 0.7820 0.7155 0.6728 0.2362 0.1324 0.2830N 40 40 40 38 38 38

    a. Signicant at 1 percent; b. signicant at 5 percent; c. signicant at 10 percent.

    27THE REGULATION OF ENTRY

  • variables are also statistically signicant, pointing further to therobustness of this evidence in favor of the tollbooth theory.

    One way to reconcile the ndings in Table V with the publicinterest theory is to argue that regulation has unintended conse-quences. Thus, benign politicians in emerging markets imitatethe regulations of rich countries with best intentions in mind, butare stymied by corruption and other enforcement failures. Thistheory is not entirely consistent with our earlier nding thatpoorer countries in fact have more entry regulations than richcountries do. A further implication of this theory is that regula-tions should have a bigger impact on corruption in poorer coun-tries. Panel B of Table V addresses this hypothesis by examiningseparately the relationship between entry regulations a